Title: Testing Theories of Social Preferences and Field Evidence
1Testing Theories of Social Preferences and Field
Evidence
2What All Models Achieve
- In the ultimatum game, low offers are rejected.
- Therefore, in the ultimatum game the proposers
make higher offers than the dictators in the
dictator game. - In the gift exchange game higher wages are
rewarded with higher effort. In the investment
game they predict positive reciprocity. - In public goods games they predict conditional
cooperation. - What about competition? Models predict that here
subjects accept more inequity Intuition It is
worthless to reject an offer, if it has no impact
on the proposer (i.e., if the proposer cannot be
punished).
3Differences in Reciprocal Behavior
Falk/Fehr/Fischbacher (Ectra)
- Q1 Who is the relevant reference agent?
- individual or group
- Q2 Is all punishment driven by inequity
aversion? - difference reduction (inequity aversion) or
retaliation (reciprocity) - Q3 What is the role of intentions?
- outcomes or intentions
4Q1 Who Is the Relevant Reference Agent?
- Three person one-shot public goods game with
punishment opportunity - 1st Stage public goods game
- Contribute 20 points (cooperate) or nothing
(defect) - Payoff
- 20 - own contribution
- 0.6 sum of all contributions
5- 2nd stage Reduce the other player's payoff at a
cost - Punishing cooperators 1 point reduction costs .3
points. - Punishing defectors 1 point reduction costs .4
points. - It is cheaper to punish cooperators.
6Q1 Prediction
- BO predict that if cooperators punish, they
punish other cooperators. - It is the cheapest way to reduce inequity because
it reduces the average payoff of the other
players most - How does Ui depend on p-I Share pi/Spj
- Inequity measured towards the whole group and not
individually - The other theories predict that if cooperators
punish, they punish defectors. - Because fairness is evaluated for each other
player separately, those are punished who
deserve punishment. Either because they have a
higher payoff (FS) or because they are unkind (DK
and FF).
7Q1 Experimental Result (N120)
- 61 percent of the subjects cooperate.
- From the cooperators
- 69 percent punish
- 69 percent punish defectors
- 7 percent punish cooperators
- From the defectors (39 percent)
- 49 percent punish, cooperators and defectors
8Q2 Is All Punishment Driven by Inequity Aversion?
- One-to-one punishment
- Same three person one-shot public goods game with
punishment opportunity, but - 1 point reduction costs 1 points, i.e., there are
higher costs of punishment - Inequity aversion models predict no punishment
because inequity cannot be reduced.
9Q2 Is All Punishment Driven by Inequity Aversion?
- 51 percent cooperate
- of these cooperators 47 percent punish two
defectors - punishment behavior is incompatible with any
equity model - Defectors do not punish.
10Q2 Is All Punishment Driven by Inequity Aversion?
- UG with constant relative share
- Rejection reduces payoffs to 10 percent
- Rejection cannot change the relative share
- Hence, BO predict no punishment
- The other theories predict rejections
P
x
y
R
R
a
r
a
r
8
.8
5
.5
2
.2
5
.5
11Exp 2 Is All Punishment Driven by Inequity
Aversion?
- UG with constant difference
- Rejection reduces payoffs by 2 points
- Rejection cannot change payoff differences
- Hence, FS and BO predict no punishment
- DK and FF predict rejections
- 82 is unkind and triggers punishment. Punishing
means a reduction of the other player's payoff.
12Q2 Experimental Results (N48)
- Punishment does not only occur to reduce
inequity. Even if inequity cannot be reduced,
people punish to reciprocate unkindness (20
percent).
13Q3 Are Intentions Important? Four Mini Ultimatum
Games
This is like the best shot game
14Intentions (ii)
15Predictions of the rejection rates of the 82
offer
- BO and FS predict the same rejection rate for
both alternatives. - These theories model fairness in a
consequentialist way and the consequence of the
82 offer is always the same. - DK predict zero rejection rate for the
alternative 100. - Subjects do not consider the 82 offer as unkind
because 100 is even more unkind. - FF predict positive rejection rates in both
cases. The rejection rate is higher in the 55
case. - Fairness is determined by the outcome and the
intention of the other subject.
16Experimental results (N45)Falk, Fehr and
Fischbacher, Economic Inquiry forthcoming)
17Q3 Proposer Behavior
- Proposer behavior is compatible with selfishness,
but also with preferences for fairness.
18Moonlighting Game(Abbink et al. 2000, Falk et
al. 2000)
- 1. Stage
- Players receive an endowment of 12 points
- Player A chooses action a ? -6, -5, , 5, 6
- a ? 0 A gives B a points
- a lt 0 A takes ?a? points from B
- In case a ? 0 the experimenter triplicates a such
that B receives 3a. - If a lt 0 player A takes ?a? points from B and B
loses ?a? points
19Moonlighting Game (ii)
- 2. Stage
- B realizes a und chooses b ? -6, -5, , 17, 18
- b ? 0 is a reward for A
- b lt 0 is a punishment
- A reward transfers b points to A
- A punishment costs B ?b? points and reduces As
income at 3?b? - Standard Prediction
- b 0 for all a
- a -6
20Results Falk et al. Testing theories of
Fairness, Intentions matter
- Reward of kind actions
- Punishment of unkind actions
21Intentions in the Moonlighting Game
- Moonlighting game as before (see above).
- But Player As decision is randomly determined
and players B know that. - Random mechanisms is based on a human choice
distribution. - Controls for the equality of choice probabilities
across computer generated and and human generated
first-mover action.
22Rewards and punishments with and without
intentions
- The same consequences trigger very different
behavior. - Questions consequentialistic notions of fairness.
- Casts doubt on the consequentialistic practice in
economics to define the utility of an action
solely in terms of the consequences.
23Intentions and Random Move Games
- If the move of the first player in the ultimatum
game is made by a random device, then - An unfair outcome is not intended by player 1.
- Therefore, unfair offers are less likely to be
rejected. - (Blount 1995)
- Same idea in gift exchange game (Charness)
- Here, high wages are rewarded with similar effort
in the treatment in which a person chooses the
wage compared to the treatment in which the wage
is randomly drawn. (though steeper slope) - In both experiments reward and punishment also
occur in the random move treatments.
24Choice plus randomness
- In Charness/Levine (2005) firms either choose
high or low wage - Workers respond with low (punish), medium or high
(reward) effort - Idea chance move changes outcomes after first
stage - Most interesting combination in treatment 2
25Best-shot Game (Mini Version) Harrison,
Hirshleifer (1989), Prasnikar/Roth (1992)
1
- Players 2 accept unequal outcome of (3.7, 0.42)
- Such distributions are rarely accepted in the
ultimatum game.
dont
contribute
2
2
contribute
contribute
dont
dont
0.42
3.7
0
0.42
3.7
0.42
0
0.42
26Conclusion
- Fairness can be captured by incorporating
preferences for fairness into the utility
function. - Models reconcile results with equal outcomes as
well as with unequal outcomes (e.g. UG vs.
competitive markets). - Fairness is evaluated individually.
- Inequity reduction is not the only reason for
punishment. - Intentions and outcome matter.
- Reciprocity models give a better description of
human behavior but at a cost in tractability.
27Field Evidence on Social PreferencesMoving
fairness research out of the lab
- Most evidence comes from the laboratory
- Delivers best and most controlled evidence
(repeated games, payoffs known, details of social
preferences etc.) - Problems
- Generalizability
- Representativeness
- Applications, economic consequences
- Types of non-laboratory evidence
- Field experiments
- Questionnaire evidence (managers, SOEP etc.)
- Observational data (work environment, donations
etc.)
28Gift-exchange in the field
- Armin Falk
- Econometrica 2006
29Contributions of the paper
- Extending the research on reciprocity and social
preferences to the field - Social preferences important for many public
economics applications - Social preferences research almost exclusively
confined to laboratory studies - Better understanding of the motives behind
charitable giving - Warm glow vs. gift-exchange
- Amount of donated money is substantial in many
nations - US 70 percent of all households donate,
exceeding 1 percent of GDP (Andreoni et al. 1996)
30Why conducting a field experiment ?
- In contrast with traditional field studies, it is
possible to create an exogenous variation in the
variables of interest - In contrast to lab experiments people take their
actions in their natural environment - Related literature
- List and Lucking-Reiley (JPE, 2002) importance
of seed money and refund policies - Frey and Meier (2005) donations to a social fund
administered by the University of Zurich
31The field experiment
- International charitable organization that helps
children in need - Active in 38 countries and engaged in long-term
development projects as well as in short-term
emergency projects - Shortly before Christmas organization sends out
roughly 10,000 solicitation letters in the area
of Zurich - 2001 mailing for homeless children in Dhaka
(Bangladesh)
32Three treatments
- No gift
- Solicitation letter
- Small gift
- Solicitation letter one postcard and envelope
- Large gift
- Solicitation letter four postcards and
envelopes - Letter gift from the children from Dhaka,
which can be kept or given to others. - Except for gifts and remark on gifts, everything
was exactly the same across treatments.
33 34Procedure
- Random allocation of donators to treatments
- All letters were sent out on December 5, 2001
- Donations routinely recorded by organization
35Hypotheses
- Warm glow feelings of internal satisfaction that
arise from helping people who are in need
(Andreoni 1989, 1995). - Willingness to donate unaffected by treatments
- Reciprocity we are obligated to the future
repayment of favors, gifts, invitations, and the
like (Cialdini 1992) support from numerous lab
experiments (Falk/Fischbacher 1999, Fehr/Gächter
2000) - Donations no gift lt small gift lt large gift
36Table 1 Donation frequencies in all treatment
conditions
37Table 1 Donation frequencies in all treatment
conditions
38Table 1 Donation frequencies in all treatment
conditions
39Table 2 Treatment differences of donation
probability
40Histogram of donations
41The organizations perspective
- Total donations 92,655 CHF
- Hypothetical total donations if all receive
- No gift 74,472 CHF
- Large gift 120,248 CHF
- Cost of gifts ?2,000 CHF
- Actual net gain 92,655 74,472 2,000 16,183
CHF (22 percent) - Hyp. net gain 120,248 - 74,472 4,800 40,976
CHF (55 percent)
42Some final thoughts
- Intertemporal substitution?
- No.
- Does gift exchange work over and over again?
- We do not know.
- Does any gift do the job?
- Probably not.
43Conclusions
- Field experiment
- Relevance of gift-exchange on top of warm glow
- Confirmation of relevance of reciprocity with
field data - Important for many public economics applications,
e.g., - Tax evasion
- Design of welfare state
- Incentive schemes
44Trust and Discrimination A Citywide Experiment
- Armin Falk
- University of Bonn
- Christian Zehnder
- University of Zurich
45Trust is important
- Economic importance of trust derives from the
fact that it enhances efficiency in the presence
of limited contract enforcement - Virtually every commercial transaction has
within itself an element of trust . (Arrow,
1972, p.357) - Trust is part of a groups social capital
- Related to level of foreign investments, growth
and efficiency of institutions (Guiso/Sapienza/Zin
gales (2006), Knack/Keefer (1997), La
Porta/Silanes/Schleifer/Vishny (1997)) - Experimental literature on economic relevance of
trust - But little is known with respect to trust and
discrimination
46Research questions
- Discrimination Do people trust strangers from
different groups differently? - Is trust discrimination taste driven or
statistical discrimination? - In-group favoritism, i.e., do people trust
strangers from their own group more than
strangers of other groups? - Individual determinants of discrimination,
in-group favoritism, trust and trustworthiness?
47Our study
- The city as a laboratory
- We study discrimination using districts of a city
as groups - Districts are natural groups, have a social
meaning and are sufficiently heterogeneous - District affiliation is relevant for economic
transactions - Social dynamics of cities and city development
48Related literature
- Discrimination
- Fershtman/Gneezy (2001)
- Bouckaert/Dhaene (2004), Haile et al. (2006), and
others - In-group favoritism
- Bernhard et al. (2006)
- Goette et al. (2005)
- Focus on ethnic discrimination
- No individual determinants
- No representative subject pool
49Design of the field experiment
- One-shot, sequential, two-player trust game
experiment - (Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe 1997)
- First and second mover receive endowment of CHF
20 - First mover
- Investment of CHF 0, 2, 4, , up to 20
- ? Money is tripled and transferred to the second
mover - Second mover
- Back transfer of CHF 0, 1, , up to CHF 80
50Design (2) Payoffs
- First mover
- 20 investment back transfer
- Second mover
- 20 3 x investment back transfer
51Design (3) District specific social capital
- Each first mover made 12 decisions (plus
beliefs), one for each of the 12 districts of
Zurich
Provides information of in-group favoritism and
discrimination on an individual level
52Zurich and its districts map shown to subjects
53Design (4) Strategy method
- Second movers responses elicited with help of
strategy method - Pay back decision for each possible investment
- Allows
- Specification of types
- Individual determinants of trustworthiness
54Design (5) Procedures
- 4000 letters sent out
- 984 subjects took part in the study
- Addresses delivered by the statistical office of
Zurich - Representative with respect to age, income and
foreigner status per district - Ss received letter, instructions, questionnaire
credible procedure - Matched and paid out in cash (letters) according
to their decisions - Mean earnings per subject about CHF 33.2
- Total spending about CHF 32,600
- We deleted addresses after payment
- Additional newspaper study (see below)
55Questionnaire plus information from statistical
office
- Socioeconomics
- Gender, age, yearly taxable income, marital
status, profession, foreigner, number of
siblings, religion, skill level (isco), district - Social capital measures and district/city
specific information - Trust question (GSS, WVS)
- Club membership (how many)
- Most people are fair or selfish
- Most people helpful or self-serving
- Most people are reliable (yes/no)
- Help provided by unknown in district
- How many friends in district
- Connected to district and city
- How many years in district and city
- How often private phone calls
- Save when walking alone in district at night
- Other
- Political orientation
- Happiness
56Results
- Discrimination
- Level and distribution of investments
- Do investments differ significantly across
districts? - Determinants
- Reciprocation
- Level and distribution
- Are investments and back transfers correlated?
Statistical discrimination - In-group favoritism
- Prevalence
- Individual determinants
- Individual determinants of trust and reciprocity
57Level and distribution of investments
- Mean 13.16 Std. dev 7.07 Median 16
58District specific discrimination
- Districts differ significantly regression of
investments on district dummies F-test prob. gt
F 0.000 - Variation investment 11 percent, coincides with
expected trustworthiness (Spearmans Rho 0.88,
plt0.001)
59Pair-wise comparison of investments in districts
p-values of pair-wise Wilcoxon-signed rank tests
60Investment ranks are correlated across districts
Consensus among districts about which are the
good and bad districts
Spearmans Rhos, excluding own district Out of 66
correlations, 61 are positive
61Additional data from a newspaper experiment how
systematic is discrimination?
- Widely read newspaper of Zurich (Tagesanzeiger),
two articles - First reporting the idea of the study, not
showing results - Invitation to a quiz Which are the two districts
that received - the lowest investments?
- the highest investments?
- Among those readers whose answers are correct,
three are randomly chosen to receive CHF 300 - Second a week later, results of the study were
reported, together with interviews (president/me) - 281 readers of the Tagesanzeiger took part
62Results from the newspaper readers
Corr inv/high Spearman's rho 0.8932, p
0.0000 Corr inv/low Spearman's rho -0.8807, p
0.0002
63Determinants of trust (discrimination)
- Economic and social status
- Income (?), education and wealth (?) (Alesina and
Ferrara (2000) Knack and Keefer (1997)) - Heterogeneity
- Ethnic heterogeneity (?) (Costa and Kahn (2002)
Alesina and Ferrara (2000)) - Religious heterogeneity (?) (Costa and Kahn
(2002) Alesina and Ferrara (2000)) - Mobility (?) (Glaeser et al. (2001) DiPasquale
and Glaeser (1998) Alesina and Ferrara (2000)) - Home ownership (?) DiPasquale/Glaeser (1998)
- Political participation (?) Feld/Frey (2000)
- Hierarchical religion (?) (Putnam 2000)
- Own district, in-group bias
64Descriptive statistics of districts
- Notes Statistical Office of Zurich and
Statistical Yearbook of the City of Zurich 2003 - Income median per capita income in 1000 Swiss
Francs - High education population fraction with at least
a college degree - Foreigners population fraction of foreigners
- Religious heterogeneity fragmentation index 1
- sum of squared population fractions of all
religions - Years of residency average number of years with
residency in the same district per person - Home ownership fraction of apartments owned by
inhabitants - Catholics fraction of Catholics
65Income
Spearman's rho 0.9161 p 0.0000
66(No Transcript)
6755 percent discriminate 45 percent dont
682. Back transfers
- How trustworthy are people from Zurich?
- Are there differences across districts?
- Is discrimination statistical or taste driven?
- Correlation between trust and trustworthiness on
the district level
69Investments and (expected) back transfers
70Distribution of individual mean reciprocal
inclination
71Back transfers
- Back transfers differ significantly across
districts regression on district dummies prob.
gt F 0.0206
72Comparison of ranks for investments and back
transfers statistical discrimination
Spearman's rho 0.6853 p 0.0139
73Trustworthiness investments and mean reciprocal
inclination by district
Spearman's rho 0.6713 p 0.0168
743. In-group Favoritism
- Do people favor strangers from their own
district? - Is that driven by taste or the expectation of
higher trustworthiness? - Individual characteristics of in-group favoritism
75In-group favoritism
- Out of the 12 districts, 11 invest higher amounts
to their own district than they invest on average
into the other districts
0.003
76Individual determinants
774. Individual determinants of trust (investments)
and trustworthiness (back transfers)
- Largely unknown, since existing evidence almost
exclusively confined to lab experiments with
homogenous subject pool - Bellemare and Kröger (2004) use a Dutch sample
- Fehr et al. (2003) combine experiment with survey
(441 Ss in Germany) - Carpenter et al. (2003) cooperation experiments
in Asian urban slums - Gächter et al. (2004) cooperation experiments
with non-student subjects in urban and rural
Russia - Dohmen/Falk/Huffman/Sunde (2006) questionnaire
data, using the GSOEP
78(No Transcript)
79Behavioral vs. questionnaire measures of social
capital
- Glaeser et al. (2000), Lazzarini et al. (2003)
- Harvard students, U. of Sao Paolo students
- No relation between general trust question and
first mover behavior in a trust experiment - Second movers behavior is correlated
- Similar Burks et al. (2000), Ben-Ner/Putterman
(1999)
80VariablesGSS/The World Bank Integrated
Questionnaire for the measurement of Social
Capital/Glaeser et al. (2000)
- trust
- Generally speaking would you say that most people
can be trusted or that you cant be too careful
in dealing with people? - reliable
- Today one cannot rely on strangers anymore. (1 to
4, binary code) - fair
- Do you think that most people would exploit you
or that they would try to be fair to you? - egoist
- Do you think that most people most of the time
try to be helpful or only follow their own
interest? - help
- If you need help, do you think that a stranger
from your district would help you? (yes, no) - phone calls
- How often have you made a private phone call last
week? (approximate number) - unsafe
- How safe from crime and violence do you feel when
walking in your district alone after dark (four
levels, binary coded) - club memberships
- In how many clubs are you a member? (number)
81(No Transcript)
82(No Transcript)
83(No Transcript)
84(No Transcript)
85Why differences to previous findings?
- More observations
- Non student subject pool
- Responses immediately after decisions
86Concluding remarks
- Behavioral measure to study trust discrimination
Significant discrimination - Determinants economic and social status, ethnic
heterogeneity - Differences endogenously reinforced
segmentation? - Higher income ? higher social capital ? higher
income - If policies want to counteract this segmentation
they must be able to diagnose the reputation
differences field experiment - Trust and trustworthiness correlated statistical
discrimination - Strong evidence for in-group favoritism
- Strong correlation of behavioral and survey
measures of trust - Important individual heterogeneity and
determinants regarding trust and trustworthiness,
discrimination and in-group favoritism - Age, education, family status, political
orientation, religion, foreigner
87Success and Prevalence of Homo ReciprocansIZA
DP 2205
- Thomas Dohmen, Armin Falk, David Huffman and Uwe
Sunde - IZA and University of Bonn
88Questions
- How prevalent is Homo Reciprocans?
- Individual determinants of reciprocity?
- Correlation of positive and negative reciprocity?
- Consequences of reciprocity for economic and
social outcomes (wages, subjective well-being,
friendships)? - Answering these questions requires
- Leaving the lab, and using a large,
representative samples - Combine measures of reciprocity with demographic
variables
89Data
- Large sample SOEP (2005 wave)
- About 22,000 individuals (age 17), 12,000
households - Representative of the population
- Each adult household member is interviewed
- Extensive socio-demographic information
- Individual characteristics
- Family and household background
- First time using questionnaire for large sample,
complements experiments with non-student
populations - Bellemare and Kröger (2004) use a Dutch sample
- Fehr et al. (2003) combine experiment with survey
- Carpenter et al. (2003) cooperation experiments
in urban slums - Gächter et al. (2004) cooperation experiments
with non-student subjects in urban and rural
Russia - Falk and Zehnder (2006) Citizens of Zurich
90Reciprocity measures
- Positive reciprocity
- If someone does me a favor, I am prepared to
return it - I go out of my way to help somebody who has been
kind to me before - I am ready to undergo personal costs to help
somebody who helped me before - Negative reciprocity
- If I suffer a serious wrong, I will take revenge
as soon as possible, no matter what the cost - If somebody puts me in a difficult position, I
will do the same to him/her - If somebody insults me, I will insult him/her
back - 7-point scales
- 1 means does not apply to me at all 7 means
applies to me perfectly - Two questions ask explicitly whether the
respondent would incur costs in order o be
reciprocal - 20,774 individuals responded to all six
reciprocity measures
91Positive Reciprocity Measures
Negative Reciprocity Measures
92Distributions of Positive and Negative Reciprocity
93Is positive and negative reciprocity correlated
within subject?
- Only weakly
- Within-person correlation between positive and
negative reciprocity 0.024 - Suggests that positive and negative reciprocity
are distinctive behavioral concepts - World more complicated than just selfish vs.
reciprocal - Different emotional responses?
- Anger appears to be important for explaining
punishment behavior in experiments (Fehr and
Gächter, 2002) - Candidates for positive reciprocity include
gratitude, or possibly anticipated guilt
associated with not rewarding - Different determinants?
94Determinants of Reciprocity
0.01
Other controls marital status, number of
children, religion, region, student, occupation,
health status, month of interview.
95Determinants of Reciprocity
0.01
Other controls marital status, number of
children, religion, region, student, occupation,
health status, month of interview.
96Determinants of Reciprocity
0.01
Other controls marital status, number of
children, religion, region, student, occupation,
health status, month of interview.
97What about students?
- Lab experiments are often criticized
- Selected student sample
- Do we overestimate the importance of social
preferences when using students? - In the GSOEP sample students are significantly
less reciprocal than non-students (both positive
and negative reciprocity) - Field experiment (Falk and Zehnder 2007)
Investment game, strategy method - Students are significantly less reciprocal, no
difference in trust
98Consequences of reciprocity
- Effort in employment relationships
- Experiments and questionnaires positive relation
between wages and effort on the job, even when
not enforceable - Hypothesized to reflect positive reciprocity
among workers - Fehr, Kirchsteiger and Riedl (1993), Fehr and
Falk (1998), Bewley (1999), Agell and Lundborg
(1997) etc. - Do we find evidence from the field that Homo
Reciprocans works harder? - Three measures of effort
- Total weekly hours, overtime hours
- Absenteeism
99Reciprocity and Work Effort
100Reciprocity and Work Effort
101Consequences of reciprocity
- Sustaining employment relationships
- Experimental evidence suggests positive
reciprocity helps sustain long-term relationships - Brown, Falk, and Fehr (2004) on endogenous
relations - Experimental and field evidence suggests workers
retaliate against employers in response to unfair
treatment - Bewley (1999) Mas and Kreuger (2004)
- Does positive reciprocity increase ability to
stay employed? - Does negative reciprocity make unemployment more
likely? - Firms fire workers to prevent retaliation
- Workers quit as a form of retaliation
- More unemployment among negatively reciprocal
workers
102Reciprocity and Unemployment
Additional controls are marital status, number of
children in the household, and religious
background.
103Success of Homo Reciprocans
- Strategic disadvantage?
- Wasting resources to engage in costly rewards and
sanctioning - Strategic advantage?
- Credible signal of reward or retaliation leads to
better treatment - Social competence friendships and networks
- Three measures of success
- Number of close friends (SOEP question)
- Income (Mincerian wage regression)
- Happiness (SOEP question)
- Important goal of human life and summarizing
success and achievement in a general way (see
Frey and Stutzer 2002)
104Success of Homo Reciprocans
105Success of Homo Reciprocans
106Success of Homo Reciprocans
107Summary
- Reciprocity rule rather than exception
- Heterogeneity and surprisingly weak correlation
between positive and negative reciprocity - Suggests that positive and negative reciprocity
are distinctive behavioral concepts - Corroborated by asymmetry in determinants
(gender, age and height) - Positive relation between positive reciprocity
and higher work effort - Positively reciprocal people report having more
close friends and a higher overall level of life
satisfaction. - In this sense, Homo Reciprocans - in the positive
domain - is in fact more successful than his or
her non-reciprocal fellows