Title: More on the invisible hand Present value
1More on the invisible handPresent value
- Today Wrap-up of the invisible hand present
value of payments made in the future
2What is the invisible hand?
- Let self-interested actions determine resource
allocation - Prices help determine how much is allocated for
production of each good or service - Rationing function
- Allocative function
3Rationing function of price
- Efficiency cannot be obtained unless goods and
services are distributed to those that value
these goods and services the most - In general, prices can obtain this goal
- We will examine exceptions in some of the later
chapters
4Allocative function of price
- As prices of goods change, some markets become
overcrowded, while others get to be underserved - Without any government controls or barriers to
entry/exit, resources will be redirected in the
long run such that economic profits get driven to
zero
5Regulated markets
- Sometimes, markets are regulated with public
interest in mind - However, the invisible hand sometimes leads to
results that were not intended - Note that this type of regulation may lead to
barriers to entry
6A regulated market of the past Airlines
- Most of you have lived a life without regulation
of major commercial airlines in the U.S. - However, in the early to mid 1970s, fares were
set such that airlines could make economic
profits if the airplane was full
7Regulation of airlines
- Airlines were required to use some economic
profits of popular routes to pay for routes that
had negative economic profits - Problem The invisible hand
- See p. 233-234 for more on piano bars and
elaborate meals - Conclusion Be careful what you regulate
8Possible solution Grant a monopoly
- This sometimes happens, but it has its own
potential set of problems - Example Regulated utilities
- Regulation may state that economic profits need
to be set to zero - What if profits are too high?
- Solution Extravagant office buildings
- Another example BC Ferries in British Columbia
- More on monopolies in Chapter 10
9Before we move on
- we need to define and understand present and
future value - Money can be invested relatively safely in many
ways - Government debt
- Savings accounts and CDs in banks
- Bonds of some corporations
10Present and future value
- Suppose that the rate of return of safe
investments is 5 - If I invest 100 today, it will be worth 105 in
a year - Working backwards, I am willing to pay up to 100
for a payment of 105 a year from now
11Working backwards
- We can calculate how much a future payment is by
discounting it by interest rate r - We calculate the present value of a future
payment as follows - Payment of M is received T years from now
- PV represents present value
12Example
- What is the present value of a 1,210 payment to
be received two years from now if the interest
rate is 10? - Plug in M 12,100, r 0.1, and T 2
- PV 10,000
13Present value of a permanent annual payment
- What happens if we receive a constant payment
every year forever? - We can add up all of the discounted payments, or
we can use a simple formula to calculate the PV
of these payments
14Present value of a permanent annual payment
- Present value of an annual payment of M every
year forever, when the interest rate is r
15Question 18 from the practice problems
- If you won a contest that pays you 100,000 per
year forever, how much is its present value if
the interest rate is always at 10 percent? - Solution M is 100,000 and r is 10, or 0.1 ?
PV is M / r, or - 100,000 / 0.1 1,000,000
16Finally, more on equilibrium
- Remember that equilibrium is not an instantaneous
process - Sometimes, trial and error is needed to find what
equilibrium is - By the time this is figured out, a new
equilibrium may emerge - The bigger the costs of finding equilibrium, the
less optimal the market generally is
17Finally, more on equilibrium
- Some people have a good ability to quickly
determine what such an equilibrium is - These people can earn money from this skill
- Example Recognizing the value of a stock before
other people
18Example Winning a contest
- Which is worth more Winning 50,000 a year
forever or 1,000,000 today? - Assume that the interest rate is 4
- The 50,000 forever has a present value of
50,000 / 0.04, or 1,250,000 - Take the 50,000 forever
19Example A stock
- Suppose that you own a stock that will pay you 1
a year forever with no risk - Assume that the annual interest rate is 5 in
this example - Value is 1 / 0.05, or 20, for the stock
20Example Winning a contest that pays you only 30
years
- Back to winning a contest, except now the two
options are - 50,000 a year for 30 years
- 1,000,000 today
- Which one is worth more?
21Example Winning a contest that pays you only 30
years
- This is a perfect example of having to think like
an economist to solve this problem quickly - You could discount each of the 30 payments
appropriately to determine how much the present
value of those payments is - However, there is another way of solving this
22Example Winning a contest that pays you only 30
years
- To solve this, we must recognize that this
problem is equivalent to the previous contest
problem, except that we must take away payments
made 30 years or more in the future - To calculate this, we must calculate how much
this contest is worth today and how much this
contest is worth 30 years from now
23Example Winning a contest that pays you only 30
years
- If you won the contest that paid forever, it
would be worth 1,250,000 - We already did this calculation
- How much is this contest worth 30 years from now?
- We need to discount 1,250,000 by thirty years
- 1,250,000 / (1.04)30 385398
24Example Winning a contest that pays you only 30
years
- The present value of 30 yearly payments is
1,250,000 385,398, or 864,602 - So, if the 50,000-per-year prize is only over 30
years, you should take the 1,000,000 prize today
25Summary
- Today, we have finished our study of the
invisible hand - We also examined discounting, and ways of summing
constant yearly payments made forever