Title: Chapter 5: The Economics of Natural Resource Systems
1Chapter 5 The Economics of Natural Resource
Systems
- Steven C. Hackett
- Humboldt State University
2Nonrecyclable, nonrenewable resources
- The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Chapter 3 dealt with static market efficiency,
which is like a photograph at a point in time.
- Dynamic efficiency is more complex
- allows for modeling how future conditions affect
present supply and demand - allows for modeling how current conditions
affect future supply and demand
3The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Recall that the static notion of efficient
resource allocation is that one cannot change
quantity from that of the equilibrium in the
snapshot time period and generate larger gains
from trade
In contrast, the dynamic notion of efficient
resource allocation is that one cannot shift
production from one time time period to another
and generate a larger present value of gains from
trade summed across all time periods.
4The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- The notion of dynamic efficiency is, ultimately,
an intuitive concept. Lets take it one step at a
time.
First, lets consider the concept of present
(discounted) value.
Would you rather have 10,000 in cash right now
or 10 years from now? Why (or why not)?
5The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Reasons why most people would rather have 10,000
today instead of 10 years from now
- If we anticipate inflation (rising prices over
time), then the purchasing power of 10,000 will
shrink over time.
- If we take the 10,000 today and invest it in,
say, government bonds, then we will have more
than 10,000 in 10 years.
6The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Reasons why most people would rather have 10,000
today instead of 10 years from now (continued)
- Pure rate of time preference I want good things
now and would rather wait for bad things. I dont
know if I will be alive in 10 years, so why wait?
- Strong current needs (e.g., college expenses,
health care expenses, basic food and shelter
needs) heightens ones pure rate of time
preference.
7The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Suppose that you have inherited 10,000, which
will be held in trust for you for 10 years.
- What is the least amount of cash you would
accept from me RIGHT NOW that would make you
willing to sign over the inheritance to me?
- Your answer to that question is your present
(discounted) value of that future 10,000 payment.
8The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- As an aside, why might your present discounted
value of a 10,000 payment 10 years in the future
differ from that of someone else?
Different life circumstances, different
investment opportunities. Other?
9The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Note The discount rate (essentially like an
interest rate) reflects the time value of money
- The rate at which the present value of a payment
shrinks as the time of payment is pushed off
further into the future
- The rate at which the future value of current
interest-earning savings grows over time.
10The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Since different people have different discount
rates, then at the prevailing market interest
rate, some people are lenders (financial
investors), while others are borrowers.
As with market equilibrium price, the equilibrium
market interest rate reflects a balancing of the
discount rates of those supplying and demanding
loanable funds.
11The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Finance is an application of economics that
focuses on time value of money. We will limit
ourselves to an elementary application of the
time value of money.
12The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Suppose that you will receive a single guaranteed
future payment i years from the present, and
your discount rate (interest rate) is r. Then
the present discounted value (PV) of that future
payment (FP) is given by the following formula
PVFP ( future payment)/(1r)i
13The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
future payment is 10,000. i 2 years from
the present. r 10 (0.10). Then PVFP 10,00
0/(10.1)2 10,000/1.21 8,264.63
14The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Based on the preceding example, the person is
indifferent between having 8,264.63 right now
and getting 10,000 two years from now.
Thus, literally, the 8,264.63 is the present
(discounted) value of 10,000 to be received two
years from now.
15The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Another point on PV If you will receive a stream
of payments over time (e.g., social security
payments), then the PV of that stream of payments
is found as follows
PVFP ?i( future payment, year i)/(1r)i
Where i 0, 1, 2, , n years.
16The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Final point on PV The preceding formulae are for
discrete time periods. If you are taking
integrals, you will want to use the continuous
discounting formula
PVFP ?FPte-rtdt Where you are integrating over
time t up to some end point T.
17The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
Our analysis of dynamically efficient resource
markets will be based on a highly simplified
modeling framework, which will provide an
accessible introduction to the topic, as well as
important insights, without overwhelming you with
complex mathematics.
18The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
Simplifying assumptions
- There is a well-functioning competitive market
for the nonrenewable resource in question (no
monopolies or cartels) - Market participants are fully informed of current
and future demand, marginal production cost,
market discount rate, available supplies, and
market price - We will look at the most basic dynamic case two
time periods today (period 0) and next year
(period 1)
19The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
Simplifying assumptions, continued
- Marginal production cost is constant (for now we
assume the law of diminishing marginal returns
does not hold) - Market demand is steady state, meaning that
demand in period 1 is the same as in period 0 (no
growing or shrinking demand)
20The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Model
- Demand P 200 Q
- Supply P 10
- Discount rate r 10 percent (0.1)
- Total resource stock Qtot 100
21The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Case 1 Ignore period 1 while in period 0 (live
for today)
Competitive market equilibrium 200-Q0 10 ? Q0
190 Problem! Qtot 100 lt 190.
Scarcity-constrained market equilibrium Q0
100 P 200 100 100.
22(No Transcript)
23PV of total gains from trade over periods 0 and 1
Period 0 CS0 (200-100)100/2 5000 PS0
(100-10)100 9000 TS0 14,000 PVTS0
14,000/(10.1)0 14,000 Period 1 Since all of
the resource was consumed in period 0, there are
no gains from trade in period 1. PVTS 14,000
24PV of total gains from trade 14,000
25The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Case 2 Divide Qtot equally over periods 0 and 1
Period 0 Q0 50, P0 200 50 150. Period 0
gains from trade CS0 (200-150)50/2
1,250 PS0 (150-10)50 7,000 TS0 8,250
26PV of total gains from trade, period 0, 8,250
27Case 2 Divide Qtot equally over periods 0 and 1
Period 1 Q1 50, P1 200 50 150. Period 1
gains from trade CS1 (200-150)50/2
1,250 PS1 (150-10)50 7,000 TS1 8,250 PV
TS1 8,250/(10.1)1 7,500
28PV of total gains from trade, period 1, 7500
29Case 2 Divide Qtot equally over periods 0 and 1
Sum of the PV of total gains from trade over
periods 0 and 1 8,250 7500 15,750
Note that 15,750 in PV of total gains from trade
from dividing the resource equally over periods 0
and 1 EXCEEDS the 14,000 in total gains from
trade when we consumed all of the resource in
period 0. Thus equal division is closer to being
dynamically efficient.
30The theory of dynamically efficient resource
markets
- Methods for solving for the dynamically efficient
allocation of the fixed stock of resource over
time
Hotellings rule The dynamic equilibrium (which
we will show is also dynamically efficient)
occurs when the PV of marginal profit (also known
as marginal scarcity rent or marginal Hotelling
rent) for the last unit consumed is equal across
the various time periods.
31Hotellings rule
- (P0-MC)/(1r)0 (P1MC)/(1r)1
Marginal profit, period 0
Marginal profit, period 1
32The Dynamically Efficient Solution
Let demand be given by P a bqi, i 0, 1, ,
n. The integral of demand is total (or gross)
benefits, aqi bqi2/2. Likewise total cost is
cqi (c is constant MC).
33The Dynamically Efficient Solution
- The dynamic equilibrium is found by solving the
following maximization problem
- Max Z ?i (aqi bqi2/2 cqi)/(1r)i ?Qtot
- ?i qi, - where i 0, 1, 2, , n. If Qtot is constraining,
and with the profit function being strictly
concave, the dynamically efficient solution
satisfies - (a bqi c)/(1r)i - ? 0, i 0, 1, , n.
- Qtot - ?i qi 0
34Solving for Dynamically Efficient Quantities in
2-Period Case
- Algebraic solution in the 2-period case is found
by applying Hotellings rule
(a bq0 c)(1r) (a bq1 c). Substitute
(Qtot q0) for q1 above. Solve algebraically q0
bQtot r(a-c)/b(2r) q1 Qtot - q0
35The Dynamically Efficient Solution
- Instead of the preceding discrete approach, one
can instead maximize the integral of net benefits
over the relevant time horizon. One would also
want to use the continuous discounting formula
e-rt instead of the discrete-period formula
1/(1r)t.
36The Dynamically Efficient Solution The r
Percent Rule of Extraction
- If we compare any two sequential periods i and
(i1) we can derive the r percent rule of
extraction
(a bqi c)1/(1r)i (a bqi1
c)1/(1r)i1 Since we were given that Pi a
bqi, the above equation can be expressed as
Hotellings rule PV(Pi MC) PV(Pi1 MC)
Note 1/(1r)i cancels on both sides,
yielding (a bqi c)(1r) (a bqi1 c)
37The Dynamically Efficient Solution The r
Percent Rule of Extraction
- If we compare any two sequential periods i and
(i1) we can derive the r percent rule of
extraction
(a bqi c)(1r) (a bqi1 c). Solving for
r ? r (a bqi1 c) - (a bqi c)/(a
bqi c) In words The discount rate r equals
the rate of growth in (undiscounted) marginal
profit over time.
38The Dynamically Efficient Solution The r
Percent Rule of Extraction
- r percent rule of extraction
r (a bqi1 c) - (a bqi c)/(a bqi
c) Simplifies to r b(qi qi1)/(a bqi
c) The equation in green above says that the
larger is the discount rate r, the faster that
the quantity allocated to future periods
declines. Thus we have a monotonically decreasing
extraction path (q0, q1, , qn) for r gt 0.
Why?
39r Percent Rule of Extraction
On the dynamically efficient path, quantity
shrinks in each successive period
On the dynamically efficient path, price rises in
each successive period
- r percent rule of extraction
Period t
Period t1
p
p
(a bqi c)
(a bqi1 c)
Pt1
pt
MC
MC
D
D
qt1
qt
qt
40r Percent Rule of Extraction
- r percent rule of extraction
Question How would this price path change if the
discount rate was equal to 0? What would this
mean?
P
Question How would this price path change if
discount rate r increased?
Dynamically Efficient price path
0
Time
41r Percent Rule of Extraction
- r percent rule of extraction
Note that the r percent rule of extraction is
derived from profit maximization by firms in a
competitive resource market, and thus arises from
Smiths Invisible Hand in a well-functioning
competitive market.
Suppose that the federal government pursued a
cheap oil policy of intervening in the market
to subsidize current consumption of oil. How
would that distort the price path from what would
be dynamically efficient?
42r Percent Rule of Extraction
- r percent rule of extraction
Note Any gap between price and marginal cost in
a market is called rent in economics. As we will
discuss in more detail later, the rent that
derives from resource scarcity is variously
called user cost, royalty, dynamic rent, scarcity
rent, or Hotelling rent.
43Dynamically Efficient Solution Simplified 2
Period Case
- Now lets apply the parameters from our problem
(a 200, b 1, c 10, r 0.1, 2 periods). The
dynamically efficient solution satisfies
(200 q0 10)/(10.1)0 ? (200 q1
10)/(10.1)1 ? 100 q0 q1
44Dynamically Efficient Solution 2 Period Case
(200 q0 10)/(10.1)0 (200 q1
10)/(10.1)1. Since q1 100 - q0, substitute
(100 - q0) for q1 and simplify 190 - q0 (190 -
(100 - q0))/(1.1) ? -q0(10.9091) 0.909190
190 ? q0 108.182/1.9091 56.667 ? q1 100
56.667 43.333
45Dynamically Efficient Solution 2 Period Case
Test P0 200 56.667 143.333 (P0
MC)/(10.1)0 133.33 P1 200 43.333
156.667 (P1 MC)/(10.1)1 133.33 Therefore,
Hotellings rule is satisfied.
46Dynamically Efficient Solution 2 Period Case
Period 0 gains from trade CS0 (200 -
143.333)56.667/2 1,605.55 PS0
(143.333-10)56.667 7,555.56 PVTS0 9,161.11
47Dynamically Efficient Solution 2 Period Case
Period 1 gains from trade CS1
(200-156.667)43.333/2 938.87 PS1
(156.667-10)43.333 6,355.48 PVTS1
7,294.35/1.1 6,631.23
Sum of PV of total gains from trade, periods 0
and 1 9,161.11 6,631.23 15,792.34. This
is 42.34 larger than a 50/50 split in Case 2.
48Dynamically efficient equilibrium
If the PV of marginal profit is equal across time
periods (Hotellings rule), then firms have no
incentive to re-arrange production over time.
This solution also generates the largest PV of
total gains from trade over time.
49Dynamically efficient equilibrium
When a resource is abundant then consumption
today does not involve an opportunity cost of
foregone marginal profit in the future, since
there is plenty available for both today and the
future. Thus, when resources traded in a
competitive market are abundant, P MC and thus
marginal profit is zero. As the resource becomes
increasingly scarce, however, consumption today
involves an increasingly high opportunity cost of
foregone marginal profit in the future. Thus as
resources become increasingly scarce relative to
demand, marginal profit (P-MC) grows.
50Dynamically efficient equilibrium
The profit created by resource scarcity in
competitive markets is called Hotelling rent
(also known as resource rent or by the Ricardian
term scarcity rent). Hotelling rent is economic
profit that can be earned and can persist in
certain natural resource cases due to the fixed
supply of the resource. Due to fixed supply,
consumption of a resource unit today has an
opportunity cost equal to the present value of
the marginal profit from selling the resource in
the future.
51Dynamically efficient equilibrium
How will the dynamically efficient allocation of
the fixed resource stock change if the discount
rate r becomes larger (and all else remains the
same)? Why?
52Dynamically efficient equilibrium
Suppose that the discount rate, demand, and
marginal cost remain the same, but the resource
stock increases. How will this change affect the
marginal profit in any given period?
53Dynamically efficient equilibrium
Given the r percent rule of extraction, if
demand and marginal cost are stationary over
time, what is the resource price path over time?
54Dynamically efficient equilibrium
- Real world Natural resource commodity prices may
rise or fall over time because - Marginal production cost might decrease
(technology improves) or increase (exploit
cheapest sources first). - Demand may grow over time unless a new
technology displaces this demand (e.g., coal
replaced firewood, natural gas replaced coal,
alt. energy replaces natural gas?), - Future demand and marginal cost cannot be known
with certainty.
55Practice Exercise
- Demand P a bQ (let a 200 and b
1) - Supply P c (let c 10)
- Total resource stock Qtot 100 2 periods (0 and
1) - From the exact solution q0 (bQtot r(a
c))/b(2r), and q1 Qtot - q0 - 1. Solve for the dynamically efficient resource
allocation for r 0, 0.05, 0.10, 0.2, and 0.5.
Build a table that with columns showing r,
q0, q1, PV of marginal profit period 0 and
PV of marginal profit period 1. There will be
five rows, one for each r value above. Provide
a brief interpretation of the impacts of rising
discount rates on the dynamically optimal price
and quantity path over time. - 2. Now suppose that Qtot 70. Build a second
table like the one in question 1 above. Provide a
brief interpretation of the impact of a smaller
resource stock on the optimal price and quantity
path.