Tobacco Policy: Economic Myths and Realities - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 55
About This Presentation
Title:

Tobacco Policy: Economic Myths and Realities

Description:

U.S. is home to only 4% of the world's smokers. Sales here declining only 2%/year. ... general readings on the economics of tobacco. Warner, Tobacco Control, ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:52
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 56
Provided by: sph90
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Tobacco Policy: Economic Myths and Realities


1
TC Online Presentations
www.tobaccocontrol.com
This presentation has been supported by a grant
to Tobacco Control from The Robert Wood Johnson
Foundation
2
Economics of TobaccoMyths and Realities
  • Kenneth E. Warner, PhD
  • Avedis Donabedian Distinguished University
    Professor of Public Health
  • University of Michigan, USA
  • November 7, 2002

3
Key to the myths
  • TI tobacco industry myth
  • TC tobacco control community myth

4
Myth 1 (TI)(the industrys favorite)
  • Tobacco is crucial to the economy. Without
    tobacco growing, cigarette manufacturing, and
    distribution and sale of tobacco products, a
    states or countrys economy will suffer job
    losses, falling tax revenues, and growing trade
    deficits.

5
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever governments consider policy that would
    discourage tobacco consumptionespecially in
    non-tobacco states and countries.
  • Intent to frighten officials into believing
    that, regardless of their health benefits,
    tobacco control measures would exact a huge
    economic toll.

6
Message
  • If government adopts policy x, cigarette sales
    will drop.
  • People will lose jobs as a consequence (tobacco
    farmers, manufacturing plant employees,
    wholesalers, retail clerks).
  • The economy will suffer from lost tax revenues,
    including (where appropriate) income and sales
    taxes associated with reduced spending by the
    newly unemployed.

7
Reality...
  • A significant economic presence does not imply
    significant economic dependence.
  • Spending on tobacco is rarely important to an
    economy.
  • Money not spent on tobacco will be spent on
    other goods and services instead, thereby
    creating a comparable number of jobs.

8
  • Real costs costs of transition to alternative
    products.
  • Given the addictiveness of tobacco, the
    transition necessarily occurs very slowly
    (cigarette consumption declining 1-2 per year in
    developed countries).

9
Case studies
  • In Michigan, a non-tobacco state, employment
    increases as tobacco consumption declines.
    Warner and Fulton, JAMA, 1994
  • In the U.S., employment would rise in all 8
    non-tobacco regions (44 states) if tobacco
    consumption fell. Warner et al., JAMA, 1996
  • Only in the 6-state tobacco bloc would employment
    fall, and by a tiny fraction of state employment.
  • Employment gains in Scotland, UK, South Africa,
    and Bangladesh falls in Canada and Zimbabwe.
    Jacobs et al., Ch. 13 in Jha and Chaloupka,
    eds., Tobacco Control in Developing Countries
    (Oxford, 2000)

10
Principal transitional costin tobacco states and
countries
  • Tobacco farmers not be thrown out of work.
  • Rather, fewer children of tobacco farmers would
    go into tobacco farming.
  • Schelling, Preventive Medicine, 1986

11
An additional economic benefit of reduced
spending on tobacco
  • Savings will accrue in health care spending, fire
    fighting, equipment maintenance and cleaning, etc.

12
(No Transcript)
13
Myth 2 (TC)(tobacco control communitys
favorite)
  • Tobacco imposes an enormous health care cost on
    society. Decreasing smoking will save billions
    of dollars in smoking-produced health care costs
    each year.

14
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever governments consider policy that would
    discourage tobacco use.
  • Intent to convince officials that the policy
    would produce major economic benefits at the same
    time that it benefits the publics health.

15
Reality...
  • Smoking-produced illness does account for a
    significant share of health care costs, e.g.,
    approximately 12 in the U.S. Miller et al.,
    Public Health Rep, 1998
  • However, in the absence of smoking, the elderly
    population would grow, as would old-age chronic
    disease costs.

16
(No Transcript)
17
Net impact
  • On balance, costs likely would fall, but only
    modestly. Net savings would be small. Warner
    et al., Tobacco Control, 1999
  • TC community should stick to the real reason to
    combat smoking its devastating health effects.

18
Myth 3 (TI)
  • A large tax increase is dangerous because it will
    reduce government revenues by decreasing legal
    cigarette sales. This will result due to
    decreased smoking and increased smuggling of
    lower-priced cigarettes from neighboring states
    or countries.

19
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever governments consider a cigarette excise
    tax increase.
  • Intent to frighten officials into believing
    that a policy intended to increase revenue will
    do the opposite, and that it will introduce
    organized crime into the state or country.

20
Reality,with regard to cigarette sales...
  • Cigarette taxation will reduce cigarette sales.
  • Increasing price is the most effective means of
    decreasing cigarette smoking, especially among
    children.
  • 10 price increase will decrease cigarette
    consumption 4 in developed countries, 8 in
    developing countries.
  • Smoking among children will fall by about twice
    as much.
  • Chaloupka et al., Ch. 10 in Jha and
    Chaloupka, 2000

21
(No Transcript)
22
Reality with regard to revenues...
  • Increased taxes invariably increase government
    revenues.
  • The percentage decline in cigarette consumption
    is smaller than the percentage increase in price
    that induces it.
  • Further, tax is only a fraction of price, so a
    given tax increase will cause a far smaller
    decrease in cigarette sales.

23
(No Transcript)
24
Reality with regard to smuggling...
  • Function of many forces
  • Price but one.
  • Others likely far more important
  • a states or countrys general tolerance for
    corruption
  • its specific efforts to combat smuggling (use of
    unique tax stamps, enforcement, etc.).
  • Informal cross-border purchases (buttlegging)
    accounts for a small share of in-state tax
    avoidance.
  • Joossens and Raw, BMJ, 2000

25
Myth 4 (TI)
  • Even if a tax increase would raise government
    revenues and decrease smoking, it is
    fundamentally unfair because its burden would
    fall disproportionately on the poor.

26
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever governments consider a cigarette excise
    tax increase.
  • Intent to appeal to officials concern for the
    welfare of the least privileged in society, and
    to their basic sense of fairness.

27
Reality...
  • Cigarette taxes are regressive.
  • A larger proportion of the poor smoke.
  • However, a tax increase may produce a progressive
    impact
  • because the rich decrease their smoking only
    slightly in response to a price increase
  • the poor decrease theirs substantially.
  • Townsend et al., BMJ, 1994

28
Furthermore...
  • Health benefit of a tax increase is distinctly
    progressive.
  • States and countries can compensate in part for
    any tax regressivity
  • e.g., by funding cessation services and
    pharmaceuticals for poor smokers.

29
(Semi-)myth 5 (TC)
  • While the health arm of the government tries to
    discourage smoking, the agricultural arm
    subsidizes it. This is hypocritical and damaging
    to the health of the nation. By subsidizing
    tobacco growing, the government is encouraging
    smoking.

30
(No Transcript)
31
Reality
  • Subsidy systems vary dramatically from one
    country to another.
  • Each countrys system needs to be evaluated
    individually.

32
Example of the U.S. system
  • A complicated web of regulations, with two
    essential components
  • setting annual quotas on tobacco production and
    minimum prices
  • limiting growing to holders or renters of
    allotments (licenses to grow).
  • The actual subsidy per se is modest.

33
Impact of the system is...
  • Direct effect raise the price of cigarettes by
    about one cent per pack, by raising the price of
    tobaccos.
  • Will decrease smoking (very slightly).
  • Zhang et al., 1997
  • Indirect effect create and reinforce political
    constituency for tobacco in Congress
  • Blocks federal tobacco control policies.
  • Thereby increases smoking.

34
(No Transcript)
35
Myth 6a (TI)
  • Cigarette advertising and promotion have no
    effect on the amount of smoking. Their only
    function, and impact, is to permit the companies
    to vie for shares of a market of fixed size.

36
(No Transcript)
37
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever the freedom of the tobacco industry to
    advertise is debated.
  • Intent to convince officials that an ad ban
    would violate the right to free speech, as well
    as adult smokers right to information.

38
(No Transcript)
39
Reality...
  • Brand-share argument runs contrary to much
    empirical evidence and makes no sense.
  • Especially in a highly concentrated market, as in
    the U.S., much brand-share marketing merely
    cannibalizes a companys own brands (e.g., Philip
    Morris controls half the market).
  • If the industry truly believed its own argument,
    it would have leapt at opportunities to ban ads.
  • In the U.S., it would save gt 10 billion/year.

40
Myth 6b (TC)
  • Cigarette advertising and promotion constitute
    one of the principal direct determinants of
    smoking, especially initiation of smoking by
    children.

41
When and how the myth is used
  • Whenever the freedom of the tobacco industry to
    advertise is debated.
  • Intent to convince officials that the crucial
    issue is the seduction of children, who are not
    legal consumers of tobacco products. TC also
    challenges the idea of a right to commercial free
    speech.

42
Reality...
  • Advertising and promotion (A/P) likely do
    increase smoking, including encouraging
    experimentation by kids.
  • No evidence points to A/P as a principal direct
    determinant of smoking, however.
  • Peer and parental behavior and role modeling by
    music and movie stars likely more important.

43
  • A/P may increase smoking through indirect
    mechanisms, as well as direct.
  • E.g., media dependence on tobacco company ad
    revenues discourages coverage of the importance
    of smoking in disease. Warner et al., New Engl.
    J. Med., 1992
  • A complete ban on A/P would be expected to
    decrease smoking by about 7. Saffer and
    Chaloupka, Journal of Health Economics, 2000

44
Myth 7 (TC)
  • The tobacco companies have moved into developing
    countries in recent years to compensate for
    declining markets in affluent nations. Tobacco
    control progress in rich countries will come at
    the price of increasingly aggressive invasion of
    poor countries by the multinational tobacco
    companies.

45
(No Transcript)
46
Reality...
  • Multinationals have moved into developing
    countries, but not because other markets are
    declining.
  • They see a market expansion opportunity in
    developing countries, due to
  • growing affluence in those countries
  • reductions in trade restrictions and
  • bulging treasuries the companies want to invest
    profitably.

47
  • Recent movement into developing countries would
    have occurred even if sales were not falling in
    developed countries.

48
Impact of declining U.S. market on global sales
and profits
  • U.S. is home to only 4 of the worlds smokers
  • Sales here declining only 2/year.
  • Therefore, U.S. sales decline represents about
    1/10th of 1 in global sales each year.
  • Further, profits in the U.S. are rising.

49
Implication
  • Tobacco control advocates in developed countries
    need not feel guilty that successes at home will
    impose a burden on people in poor countries.
  • To the contrary, tobacco control success in the
    developed nations is likely to serve as a model
    for future tobacco control in developing
    countries.

50
Conclusion
  • The tobacco industrys economic arguments are a
    bait-and-switch tactic.
  • Deflect attention from the health consequences of
    smoking.
  • Find a receptive ear in this domain.
  • TC community feels compelled to fight back on the
    economic battlefield.

51
  • Each sides economic arguments contain
    self-evident grains of truth, making them quite
    compelling.
  • Each sides arguments distort (sometimes destroy)
    the far more complicated reality.

52
Irony
  • To economists, the economic issues in tobacco are
    interesting but not fundamentally important.
  • Arguments are most important to people who do not
    understand them
  • politicians
  • government officials
  • journalists

53
but if one wants to lend credence to the
industrys numbers
  • Compare 400,000 tobacco jobs per year in the
    U.S. to 400,000 deaths caused by tobacco
  • Each tobacco job, for one year, comes at the cost
    of one smokers losing 15 years of life.
  • The job is replaceable. The life is not.

54
True bottom line
  • is measured not in dollars and cents, but
    rather in the grief of injured smokers and their
    loved ones.

55
Recommended general readings on the economics of
tobacco
  • Warner, Tobacco Control, 2000.
  • Curbing the Epidemic Governments and the
    Economics of Tobacco Control (World Bank, 1999)
  • Jha and Chaloupka, eds., Tobacco Control in
    Developing Countries (Oxford, 2000)
  • Chaloupka and Warner, Ch. 29 in Culyer and
    Newhouse, eds., Handbook of Health Economics,
    vol. 1B (Elsevier, 2000)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com