Title: Industrial Organization MarieLaure Allain and Jrme Pouyet
1Industrial Organization Marie-Laure Allain and
Jérôme Pouyet
2Oligopolistic competition
- Imperfect competition between firms that have
some degree of market power - Happens whenever there is a limited number of
firms in a market (i.e. always) - Barriers to entry (fixed costs, institutional
barriers) - Product differentiation (transport costs,
different production process, quality
differenciation) - Strategic interactions of various decision makers
- Oligopolistic market structure reactive
environment - Non-cooperative game theory
- Distortions price, quantities, quality,
incentives (investment, innovation), services - Some instruments can be changed more quickly than
others difference between long run /short run.
3Imperfect competition and welfare
- Welfare effect of imperfect competition depends
from numerous factors - Market structure (number of firms, threat of
entry, degree of differentiation) - Firms behavior (collusion, equilibrium selection,
contracts, exclusion) - Caveat competition restrictions may sometimes be
welfare-enhancing
4Competition policy
- Competition policy is the set of policies and
laws which ensure that competition in the
marketplace is not restricted in such a way as to
reduce economic welfare (Motta). - US Sherman Act (1890, agreements and contracts,
monopolization practices), Clayton Act (1914,
mergers), Robinson Patman Act (1936, price
discrimination) - EU Treaty of Rome (1957, Articles 81and 82 after
renumbering by the Treaty of Amsterdam) - Control of market structures avoid
monopolization - by merger control
- US Brown Shoe (1962)
- EU MCI World Com/Sprint, 1999 (rejected by both
EC and US DoJ), General Electric / Honeywell
(approved by US DoJ, rejected by EC) - by divestiture or dismantlement (Standard Oil
Company, 1911 ATT, 1982 Consent Decree) - Control of competitive behavior prevent
welfare-restricting agreements and contracts
51) Cournot competition model (1838)
- First paradigm of imperfect competition
- Quantities are the strategic variable
- e.g. small-scale daily markets where prices
adjust to clear the market - Tour operators book the quantity of flights and
hotel rooms approximately 18 months in advance.
Once catalogues are published, prices adjust in
the short-run. - See later the Kreps-Sheinkman model
- One-stage game
- n firms choose their quantities simultaneously
- The price is then fixed by equalizing demand and
supply - Firm is objective is to maximize its profit
6Cournot competition
- Assuming that each profit function is
strictly concave in qi and twice differentiable,
the FOCs implicitely define firm is reaction
function - The second term (ii) is negative because market
price responds to the quantity (the firm is not
atomistic) negative externality towards the
competitors, so that Cournot total quantity is
higher and market price lower than monopoly
quantity. - The reaction function is downward sloping iff
7Cournot competition
- Comparison with the monopoly (Lerner index) in
equilibrium,
8Cournot competition
- With linear demand and constant marginal costs (
assuming there is not too much cost
heterogeneity) - Remark each profit increases in the average
marginal cost, and decreases in the number of
firms.
9Technical discussionin the two-firms case (see
Tirole, 5.7)
- Existence of a pure strategy equilibrium
- Sufficient conditions
-
- sufficient for this convex cost function and
concave demand - FOC then define continuous reactions function
- ( uniquely defined if )
- For the reaction functions to intersect
- each firm would produce a positive quantity if
it were a monopoly - even if i produces its monopoly quantity, j
still produces a strictly positive quantity
10Existence of a pure strategy Cournot equilibrium
Cournot equilibrium
11Existence of a pure strategy Cournot equilibrium
- Problems of non existence
- When the profit function is not concave, reaction
functions may not be continuous for instance if
the demand is convex enough - Jumps in the reaction functions may hinder the
existence of pure strategy equilibria - Uniqueness
- Even when it exists the equilibrium may not be
unique - Sufficient condition whenever they intersect,
is steeper than - Sufficient for this
12Stackelberg competition
- Sequential choice of quantities
- Simple example
- 2 firms
- linear demand
- Constant marginal cost c
- Determine the Cournot equilibrium
- Determine the Stackelberg equilibrium when 1 is
the leader - First-mover advantage
- Remark in some games, first mover drawback
132) The Bertrand paradox (1883)
- Framework
- 2 identical firms produce the same good
(perfectly homogenous) with constant marginal
cost c - Price is the strategic variable
- For a given price p, demand is D(p)
- More precisely, all the demand goes to the less
expensive firm
14The Bertrand equilibrium
- The only Nash equilibrium is such that both price
pc and get zero profit - All consumers buy at the lowest price
- Zero demand for 1 if 2 undercuts
- Boils down to perfect competition, with only two
firms on the market.
153) Resolutions of the Bertrand paradox critical
assumptions
- Search and switching costs
- Symmetry of costs and constant return to scale
- Capacity constraints may limit the ability of a
firm to undercut its rival and clear the market - Edgeworth criticism (Kreps and Sheinkman)
- Horizontal differentiation Hotelling, Salop
- Vertical differentiation
- Repeated Bertrand game collusion (folk theorems)
16Bertrand competition and asymmetric firms
- Example in the Bertrand framework, suppose that
firm 1 has a lower marginal cost than firm 2 - Determine the equilibrium of the price
competition game.
17Search costs
- Suppose buyers are not informed initially about
the firms prices. They choose one firm randomly
and discover the price. If they want to choose
another firm, they have to pay a search cost to
discover the other firms price. - There exists an equilibrium (BPE) in which both
firms set the monopoly price - Given these prices and the search cost, a buyer
has no incentive to visit another firm once he
has randomly chosen (note buyers beliefs) - Given this behavior from the buyers, a firm has
no incentive to decrease its price. - Example restaurants for tourists vs. for locals
(differentiation between firms wrt search costs).
18Switching costs insights
- Framework
- Two symmetric firms
- Two periods (t1,2), no discounting (d1)
Marginal cost at each period t - One buyer with utility at date t
- Switching cost s for the buyer to change his
supplier between dates 1 and 2. - Firms cannot commit to a sequence of prices.
19Switching costs insights
- At date 2, the firm who sold in period 1
exercises her market power by pricing - Foreseeing this, firms are willing to price at
(at a loss) at date 1 to capture the
buyer who will become a valuable follow-on
purchaser at date 2 - Bargain then ripoff strategy discounts first
to attract consumers, then increased prices on
the captive demand - Conclusion in this basic setting, switching
costs do not affect the life-cycle price - Competition over time
203.1) The Edgeworth criticism (1925)
- Edgeworth As firms have limited capacities,
they are not able to produce an infinite quantity
and may not be able to produce enough to satisfy
all the demand there may be some residual demand
for a firm setting a price higher than the
Bertrand equilibrium price (marginal cost pc) - Kreps and Scheinkman (1983, Bell Journal of
Economics) Quantity precommitment and Bertrand
competition yield Cournot outcome
21KS-The model
- 2 firms produce a homogeneous good at the same
marginal cost c - Demand D(p)d-p
- Benchmark Cournot equilibrium
22KS-The model
- The game
- 1) firms 1 and 2 simultaneously choose their
capacities X1 and X2, with the unit cost c - 2) firms 1 and 2 simultaneously set their final
prices p1 and p2 - Efficient rationing rule
23KS - equilibrium
- Proposition there exists an equilibrium where
the firms choose binding capacities equal to the
Cournot outcome - In this equilibrium the firms make strictly
positive profits - Note the result depend strongly on the choice of
the efficient rationing rule (Cf. Davidson and
Deneckere, 1986)
24KS - proof
- First step consider stage 2
- Assume
- Define
- Both firms price above
- Assume
25KS - proof
- Both firms set the same price
- Assume
- Either 2 satisfies all its demand D10
- Or
- Locally,
26KS - proof
- Both firms thus set the same price above
- Assume
- Consider i such that
- It is profitable for i to undercut
27KS - proof
- The only possible equilibrium is thus
- It is an equilibrium (straightforward)
- Each firm sells its capacity
- Looking for SPE, stage 1 is equivalent to the
Cournot game each firm chooses its Cournot
quantity as a capacity. - Conclusion the choice of a capacity is a
pre-commitment that enables the firms to relax
further competition and gain strictly positive
Cournot profits instead of zero Bertrand profits. - Role of capacity investment as a precommitment
see Gelman and Salop, Judo economics (part II)
283.2) Product differentiation
- Another crucial assumption of the Bertrand model
is the homogeneity of the product - Yet in practice, some consumers may continue to
buy from the most expensive firms because they
have an intrinsic preference for the product sold
by that firm notion of differentiation - Two types of product differentiation
- Horizontal differentiation for identical prices,
consumers choose different products - Vertical differentiation for identical prices,
consumers choose the same product
29Horizontal differentiation
- Even at a given quality, consumers have
different tastes - Consumers preference for product specificities
create horizontal differentiation - Spatial localisation matters ( temporal
availability, one-stop-shopping and product
complementarities,) - Information on product availability is also
relevant - The cross elasticity of demand is not infinite
residual demand for the high-price product
30The Hotelling model (1929)
- Stability in competition, Economic Journal
- Continuous and uniform location of consumers
along a segment (linear city, or tastes) - Two firms are located on the segment and compete
in prices to sell the same good produced at zero
marginal cost - Price decisions are taken once location is fixed
(price is more flexible than location) - Consumers pay a transportation cost to go to the
shop to purchase the good (or utility loss when
not consuming their preferred variety)
cdistance to the shop - Each consumer purchases one unit of the good
irrespective of the price (covered market
assumption) at the lower delivered cost
(including transportation cost)
31Hotellings result
- Given the locations a and b,
- For equal prices, a buyer prefers the firm which
is closer to his location - As long as the two prices are close enough
- the indifferent consumer is such that
- Profits
- Hotelling derives the FOC to determine the final
equilibrium prices given a and b. Given a, firm
2s profit is increasing in b Hotelling
concludes with a principle of minimum
differentiation aggregation of the firms who
chose to locate as close as possible to each
other.
32The criticism of dAspremont, Gabszewicz and
Thisse
- In On Hotellings Stability in competition,
Econometrica 1979 , they prove that the price
solution is not a Nash equilibrium when both
sellers are close to the center of the segment,
but not at the same location. - If abl (both firms at the same localisation)
there exists a unique price equilibrium Bertrand - If abltl, but both firms are close to the center,
there exists a profitable deviation in the
pricing game, as the profit function is not
concave
33- As Hotelling concludes that both firms have a
tendency towards the center, this deviation
occursNo equilibrium in the two-stage game. - Introducing quadratic transportation costs solves
this problem price eq. solution everywhere.
However, the result is reversed maximum
differentiation. - The game
- (1) firms choose locations simultaneously
- (2) firms choose prices simultaneously
34Hotelling quadratic transport costs
- Demand is derived from the indifferent consumer
- The equilibrium prices are thus
- It is straightforward that
- ? Maximum differentiation
35Hotelling - Final remarks
- Two opposite effects
- Market share effect given the price structure,
each firm wants to move toward the center to
increase its market share - Strategic effect if i comes closer to j, then j
reduces its price and increases price competition - The strategic effect dominates the market share
effect - Horizontal differentiation is a very realistic
answer to the Bertrand paradox - Limit demand is inelastic as each consumer
consumes exactly a single unit of this commodity
irrespective of its price (market is covered by
assumption v must be sufficiently large) - Equilibrium location is not socially optimal
should minimize transport costs (1/4,3/4). - Empirically, some industries choose maximal
differentiation (specialist food retails), others
seem to converge (clothing,)
36Vertical differentiation
- Competition with different qualities
- Two firms, 1 and 2
- qualities resp.
- Aggregate mass of buyers
- Heterogeneity indexed uniformly by
- Unit demand, valuation for quality given by
- Assume the market is covered in equilibrium (to
be checked ex post)
37Vertical differentiation
- The marginal buyer is indifferent between the two
goods - Demand faced by the two producers
38Vertical differentiation
- Firms set their prices simultaneously in
- equilibrium,
- Profits are
39Vertical differentiation and entry
- When the heterogeneity between buyers is low, the
low quality producer makes zero profit while the
high quality producer makes a strictly positive
profit - Intuition on the consequences for entry
- a firm entering the market with a low quality
cannot compete with the high quality producer. - A firm entering with a high quality triggers a
tough price competition - See Shaked and Sutton, 1983