Title: Did the Chilean Pension Reform Postpone Retirement?
1Did the Chilean Pension Reform Postpone
Retirement?
- Evidence from Chile
- Alejandra C. Edwards and Estelle James
- Presented at OECD, Paris, 2006
2Chilean reform of 1981
- Research shows large impact of pension systems on
retirement age, but no empirical test of DC - Chilean reform replaced DB with DCcontributions
go into individual accounts, pension depends on
accumulation, on actuarial basis - Old system had incentives to pension early and
deterrents to work after pensionhigh payroll
tax, no incremental benefit, work in same job
restricted - New system removed these biases and cut payroll
tax, especially for pensioners who were exempt
3System as a whole is actuarially fair, but may
not be actuarially fair to each individual
- Some individuals have higher time preference,
want to save less or start dissaving sooner, want
to invest in different (riskier?) portfolio, want
more flexible payouts, expect to die early - These individuals wont view system as
actuarially fair to them and still face
substantial tax component
4New system should raise lfpr of older workers
thru 2 channels
- Higher retirement age and deterred early pension,
so liquidity constrained workers workis later
pensioning due to incentives from actuarial
fairness or new constraints? - Increased work propensities among pensionersis
this due to actuarial fairness or exemption from
payroll tax, therefore higher net wage? - We expect smaller change among non-pensionersnot
exempt from payroll tax and many are not in any
pension system
5Pension probabilities among 50-64 fall after 1981
reform (up before)
6LFP trends reverse after reform(went down
before, up afterwards)
7particularly among pensioners
8Aggregate trends are consistent with our
hypotheses.
- Can we isolate the effect of reform from
variations in individual and macro-economic
variables? Answer Yes, with some caveats - We use a difference in differences approach
- We measure marginal behavioral change by cohort
after reform
9Data set from Greater Santiago Area Household
Surveys 1960-2004
- Individual level data on
- Labor force participation
- Demographic characteristics
- Labor and pension income
- Shortcomings
- It is not longitudinal, no retrospective data
- But we can build synthetic cohorts--people with
same birth year, observed at different ages. - We dont know whether individual is affiliated,
which system, age pension started, or type
pension , but we use birth cohort as proxy for
new system membership
10Birth cohort proxies new system membership
- Those under age 50 in 1981 were more likely to
joint new system and fraction in new system is
larger for each birth year after 1931. - We define post-reform cohorts as those born after
1931. Reform effect is predicted to grow with
each cohort after 1931, until everyone is in the
new system and has adapted to its incentives.
11We organize data by cohort
- 31,500 observations men 50-70 years old
- 35 birth cohorts, born 1916-50, pre-reform born
1916-30 post-reform born 1931-50 - Continuous analysis prob. of new system
membership proxied by birth year minus 1931 - Discrete analysis 5 or 10 birth years grouped
and assigned dummies - COH1 and 2 are pre-reform, born 1916-25
1926-30, COH3, 4, 5 and 6 are post-reform, born
1931-35, 1936-40, 1941-45, 1946-50 - we interact dummies with age
- we calculate marginal effect for each cohort
- Interact reform variables with pension status to
separate impact on pensioners and non-pensioners
12Probit analysis estimates 1) pension
probabilities and 2) lfp rates as function of
- Individual characteristics measuring the relative
value of time Age, schooling, marital status,
presence of young children, nonlabor income - Time-specific labor market conditions economic
cycle, unemployment rate, GDP trend - Lfp rate also a function of pension status,
amount, pseudo-replacement rate - Pre and post-reform cohorts and age group
interactions
13Results pension prob. by age fall
- Pension rates vary with individual
characteristics as expected, and increase with
unemployment - Pension rates fall if worker reaches 50 after
reform - Coh31 is significantly negative for all ages gt 50
- Discrete dummies for each 5-year cohort
- For 50-59, pension rates start falling with COH3
(46-50 in 1981), accumulated reduction is 12.7
points by COH6 - This is 67 of starting pension rate for age
group - For 60-64, pension rates start falling with COH4
(41-45 in 1981) by 5.2 points, 15 of starting
pension rate - Full cohorts not yet observed total effect
larger - For 65-70, pension rates stay the same (few
observations, no new restrictions apply after age
65) - Reason for postponement keeping money in new
system rewarded, early pension restricted in new
system
14Results labor force participation rates of older
workers rise
- Participation rates vary with individual
characteristics and macro variables as expected - Pension status, size of pension and
pseudo-replacement rate have strong negative
effect on lfpr, as expected. Real pension size
rose, but not as fast as wages so
pseudo-replacement rate fell over this period,
explaining part of aggregate increase - After all controls, participation rates rise
sharply for individuals reaching 50 after reform - (1) more people remain non-pensioners, much
higher lfpr than pensioners (77 percentage
points) - (2) lfpr among pensioners increases
- Participation rates of prime age males and older
non-pensioners stable
15Reform effects among pensioners
- In continuous model, interaction of pension and
coh31 is 1.8 pp per birth year since 1931 for age
50-65, .6 pp for gt 65 - In discrete cohort model, effect also
concentrated in pensioners, starts with COH3 or 4 - For ages 50-59, accumulated increase is 20
pp100 higher than starting lfpr - For ages 60-65, accumulated increase is 18
pp125 higher than starting lfpr - For 65-70, accumulated increase is 5
ppincomplete - System is still in transitionpositive marginal
effect for last cohort observed
16Macroeconomic effects
- This implies 22 increase in older labor force,
or 4.4 increase in aggregate labor force and GDP - Implies growth rate increases .21 per year over
20 years - Total increase will be higher once new steady
state is reached and as in older age groups
grows
17Policy implications
- Incentives from shift to new system have had
positive effects on supply of older workers - Normal pension age raised, conditions for early
pension tightened and penalties for postponement
removed - Pension growth is actuarially fair with
contributions - Pensioners exempted from payroll tax
- Which is more importantactuarial fairness or
early pension constraints exemption from taxes? - Large drop in pension prob before 65 not after,
suggests that early retirement constraints play
major role - Large lfp effect among pensioners suggests that
exemption from payroll tax plays a key role - Absence of lfpr effect among non-pensioners
implies that actuarial fairness is less
important, or that most non-pensioners arent in
any formal system
18Future research with new longitudinal data set
- Do workers take pension as soon as eligible?
- Has lfp increased among old system and no-system
affiliates? What is the differential effect of
new system, once individual identity is known? - Do workers near MPG behave differently from other
workers (different work incentives)