Title: Metodi sperimentali applicati alla domanda di trasporto
1Metodi sperimentali
applicati alla domanda di trasporto
-
- Alessandro Innocenti
- Università di Siena
- in collaborazione con
- Patrizia Lattarulo (IRPET) e Maria Grazia
Pazienza (Università di Firenze) - Seminario interno IRPET Toscana
- Firenze 26 ottobre 2011
2The view of a cognitive economist
-
- Many experimental economists seem to view their
enterprise as akin to silicon chip production.
Subjects are removed from all familiar contextual
cues. Like the characters 'thing one' and 'thing
two' in Dr. Suess' Cat in the Hat, buyers and
sellers become 'persons A and B', and all other
information that might make the situation
familiar and provide a clue about how to behave
is removed. - George Loewenstein (1999)
3The context free experiment
- The context-free experiment is an elusive goal
and - not necessarily a good thing
- Games in the laboratory are usually played
without labels but subjects inevitably apply
their own labels - A major discovery of cognitive psychology is how
all forms of thinking and problem solving are
context-dependent (language comprehension) - The laboratory is not a socially neutral context,
but is itself an institution with its own formal
or informal, explicit or tacit, rules
4The context free experiment
5Label matters - Wasons test
- Jones-Sudgen (2001)
- Wasons selection task to test positive bias
confirmation tendency, when testing an existing
belief, to search for evidence which could
confirm that belief, rather than for evidence
which could disconfirm it -
- Correct response is facilitated by adding
thematic content to the task, i.e. by providing
a cover story which accounts for the statement
and gives some point to the selection task
subjects become more rational and not less
rational
6Travel mode choice
- Aim to extend previous experimental evidence on
travel mode choice by providing subject not only
with information acquired through personal
experience, but also with actual travel times of
the alternative non chosen travel modes -
- Key Findings
- subjects show a marked preference for cars
- are inclined to confirm their first choices
- exhibit a low propensity to change travel mode
7Background literature
- Experimental literature on travel mode choice
relies widely on studies on route choice - Common object coordination games, i.e. the
payoff each traveler can achieve is conditional
on her/his ability to diverge from or to converge
with other travelers choices - Selten et al. (2007), Ziegelmeyer et al. (2008),
Razzolini-Dutta (2009) provide laboratory
evidence that choices between route A and route B
generate Nash equilibria
8Background literature
- Evidence from the field shows that these learning
processes are affected by cognitive biases
(Kareev et al. 1997, VerplankenAarts 1999) - To provide travelers with more accurate
information on actual travel times does not
necessarily increase their propensity to minimize
travel costs (Avineri-Prashker 2006) - Information is better processed when travelers
lack long-term experience on travel time
distribution (Ben EliaErev-Shiftan 2008)
9Background literature
- Cars are generally perceived as travel means
giving people the sensation of freedom and
independence - The costs associated to car use are undervalued
because they not paid contextually with car use - Pollution or social costs due to car accidents
are often neglected and not easily computable - These factors explain the presence of a general
propensity to use private cars and of a
psychological resistance to reduce it - Van Vugt et al. 1995, Tertoolen et al. 1998,
Bamberg et al. 2003
10The design
- 62 undergraduate students (31 women and 31 men)
from the University of Firenze - Computerized experiment
- Between subject
- Each session lasted approximately an hour
- Average earnings 18.4 euro
11The design
- 1) Choice between car or metro
- Metro travel costs are fixed, while car costs
are uncertain and determined by the joint effect
of casual events and traffic congestion - 2) Choice between car or bus
- Car and bus are both uncertain and determined by
the combination of casual events and traffic
congestion. -
- Travelers utility only depends on travel times,
which are converted in monetary costs. After each
choice, subjects are informed of actual times of
both available modes, but not of the probability
distributions determining casual events
12The design
13The design
- Metro Car treatment- the expected total costs of
car and metro were equivalent if the share of car
users was not greater than 55 - Bus 1.0 Car treatment - the expected total costs
of car and bus were equivalent if the share of
car users was not greater than 55 - Bus 0.8 Car treatment- the expected total cost of
the bus was 20 lower than car expected total
costs if the share of car users was not greater
than 55.
14Results Preference for Cars
15Results Preference for cars
16Results Preference for cars
17Results Preference for cars
18Results Preference for cars
19Results First Choice Effect
20Results First Choice Effect
21Results Travel Mode Stickiness
- The first choice effect decreases the propensity
to change travel mode - Only 28.6 of the subjects in the metro treatment
and 39 of the subjects in the bus treatments
change more than 20 times over 50 periods. - On average, subjects change mode 17.7 times in
the metro treatment and 18.0 times in the bus
treatments
22Conclusions
- Travel mode choice is significantly affected by
heuristics and biases that lead to robust
deviations from rational behaviour - Travelers choose modes using behavioural rules
that do not necessarily involve the minimization
of total travel costs. - Subjects show a marked preference for cars, are
inclined to confirm their first choice and
exhibit a low propensity to change travel mode.
23Conclusions
- In repeated travel mode choice, available
information is not properly processed, cognitive
efforts are generally low and rational
calculation play a limited role - The habit of using cars should be assumed to be
relatively resistant, to the effect of economic
incentives - Little progress can be expected by asking
travelers to voluntarily reduce the use of a car
or even by subsidizing public transport costs
24Back to Methodology
- One of the basic tenets of laboratory methodology
is that the use of non-professional subjects and
monetary incentives allows making subjects
innate characteristics largely irrelevant - In our experiment, it is as if subjects take into
the lab the preferences applied to real choices
and stick to them with high probability - This inclination to prefer cars tends to override
the incentives effect - Labels give subjects clues to become less and not
more rational
25Internal vs. External Validity
- Internal validity - ability to draw confident
causal conclusions from one's research - External validity - ability to generalise from
the research context to the settings that the
research is intended to approximate - Experiments have the reputation of being high in
internal validity but low in external validity - Field studies of being low in internal validity
but high in external validity
26The power of labels
- In our experiment, subjects behavior depends
more on prior learning outside the laboratory
than on expected gains in the laboratory - Labels have the power to increase external
validity with a minimal sacrifice of the internal
validity - To test learning and cognitive models, it is
necessary to remind and to evoke contexts which
may activate emotions, association, similarities
in the laboratory
27Some examples
- Tram
- http//www.youtube.com/watch?vH1XrL_U38-c
- Metro
- http//www.youtube.com/watch?vdYmsmWqCV0A
- Car
- http//www.youtube.com/watch?NR1vSk-WlKTtExA
- Progetto ALBO
- http//www.progettoalbo.it/images/video/trailer.mp
4