Title: Trade and the Environment
1Chapter 10
- Trade and the Environment
2Key Questions
- What are the classical theorems of international
trade and the implications of extending them to
environmental resources? - When does trade liberalisation damage the
environment and if so does it matter? - Do countries competitively reduce environmental
standards and if so for what purpose? - Does banning trade in products made from
endangered species necessarily augment stock
size? - Does adherence to the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade unduly constrain attempts to
tackle environmental problems? - Does the empirical evidence suggest that
differences in the stringency of environmental
regulations are a major determinant of trade
flows?
3Viewpoints
- Concerns expressed by environmentalists about
international trade - Will gains from trade liberalisation be
outweighed by the damage to the environment? - Is there an incentive for countries to engage in
ecological dumping where one country lowers its
emissions standards to gain some competitive
advantage? - Will footloose industries migrate to pollution
havens? - Will countries competitively lower environmental
standards to generate trade benefits resulting in
a race to the bottom? - What about the environmental impact of
transporting goods internationally? -
- Businessmen often argue that environmental
regulations -
- will result in the loss of jobs, and that
- the production of pollution intensive goods will
merely be pushed offshore. - Politicians are concerned about the resulting
unemployment. - Debate about the impact of international trade on
the environment grew noisier in the early 1990s,
mainly in response to fears about the possible
impact of the proposed North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) between Canada, the US and
Mexico. Standing on a populist platform former US
presidential candidate Ross Perot claimed that
NAFTA would result in a giant sucking sound of
jobs flowing to Mexico and recommended that
Mexican goods be barred from entering the US
unless they were produced under conditions
meeting US standards for environmental
protection. The exchange between Daly (1993) and
Bhagwati (1993) is between two of the chief
protagonists in the debate over NAFTA. -
4Debate
- Debate about the impact of international trade on
the environment grew noisier in the early 1990s
... - Mainly in response to fears about the possible
impact of the proposed North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) between Canada, the US and
Mexico. - Former US presidential candidate Ross Perot
claimed that NAFTA would result in large scale
flow from USA to Mexico and recommended that
Mexican goods be barred from entering the US
unless they were produced under conditions
meeting US standards for environmental
protection. - The exchange between Daly (1993) and Bhagwati
(1993) is between two of the chief protagonists
in the debate over NAFTA.
5Free Trade and Welfare
- Many economists believe that free trade improves
economic welfare. - Some welcome the fact that industries might wish
to relocate in countries with low standards. - For them it just demonstrates that differing
endowments are the basis of trade. - Economists do not generally accept the argument
that countries ought to share the same
environmental standards, given the existence of
large differences in per capita incomes and
population densities between countries. - Many economists therefore would see no reason for
biophysical standards and environmental taxes to
be harmonised. - Many would also contend that although changes in
environmental regulation might result in
temporary unemployment, changes in the exchange
rate will ultimately restore the trade balance. - Calls for trade restrictions made on
environmental grounds should be viewed with
suspicion as they might be motivated by
protectionist concerns.
6Structure of this Chapter
- Review of the traditional theory of trade
- Extension of this theory to incorporate
environmental resources. - Why might a country have an advantage in the
production of environmentally intensive
commodities. - Partial equilibrium analysis of the effects of
moving from a position of autarky (no trade) to a
system of free trade with and without the
requisite controls on the production of
environmental externalities. - We show that the problem is the absence of
economically efficient environmental policy
rather than trade liberalisation per se. - General equilibrium model analysis of the effect
of trade liberalisation on welfare. - Consideration of situations in which governments
might attempt to manipulate environmental
standards in order to benefit national producers.
- Development of a model in which jurisdictions
compete in order to attract capital. - Is this likely to result in an erosion of
environmental standards? - The role played by the World Trade Organisation
(WTO) in policing the global trading system. - What, according to the WTO, is the difference
between justifiable and unjustifiable
restrictions on trade enacted in the name of
environmental protection? - Brief overview and critique of attempts to test
the proposition that environmental regulations
explain trade flows and patterns of Foreign
Direct Investment (FDI).
7Traditional trade theory
- Traditional trade theory characterised by a
number of theorems. These include - Heckscher-Olin theorem
- Stolper-Samuelson theorem
- Rybczinski theorem
- Factor price equalisation theorem.
- These are covered by any standard textbook on
international trade e.g. Bhagwati and Srinivasan
(1983). - Like Rauscher (1999) and Steininger (1999) we
wish to consider the implications of these
theorems when environmental factors of production
are brought into the picture alongside capital
and labour. -
8The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem
-
- A fundamental proposition regarding the pattern
of trade between two economies. - The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem suggests that trade
is determined by differences in factor
endowments. - A country will export those goods relatively
intensive in its abundant factor of production
and import those goods relatively intensive in
its scarce factor of production. - For example, a country having an abundant supply
of capital will find it cheaper to manufacture
goods whose production is capital intensive. - The country is said to have a comparative
advantage in the production of such goods. - Post free trade the consumption of the labour
intensive goods will increase because of an
increase in national income and a positive
substitution effect whereas the consumption of
capital intensive goods may or may not increase. - Taken as a whole, consumers unambiguously reach a
higher level of welfare.
9Heckscher-Ohlin theorem assumptions
-
- The theorem rests on a number of assumptions
- Countries have identical constant returns to
scale technologies. - Countries have identical tastes.
- There are no impediments to trade and no
transport costs. - There are two goods, two factors of production
available in fixed quantities, and two countries
one of which is small and the other one large
representing the rest of the world. - Factors of production are immobile.
10Environmental extension (1)
- How can the HO theorem be extended to include
environmental and natural resources as factors of
production? - The exports of many countries reflect their
exploitation of particular natural resource
endowments. But the observation that countries
with, say, deposits of bauxite should
specialise in the production of bauxite ore is
not especially insightful.
11Environmental extension (2)
- But environmental resources include air, soil and
water quality, and the capacity of the
environment to assimilate the unwanted by
products of economic activity. - From our perspective a country is therefore well
endowed with environmental resources when it is
sparsely populated and has a higher assimilative
capacity. - HO theorem implies that countries well endowed
with environmental resources should specialise on
the production of environmentally damaging goods.
12Endowment Regulation
- Ultimately, a countrys endowment of
environmental resources is determined by
environmental regulation. - The stringency of environmental regulation should
reflect the populations appetite for
environmental quality. - The stringency of environmental policy is
endogenous so the growth in income that
accompanies trade liberalisation might increase
the stringency of environmental policy and
therefore reduce the endowment of environmental
factors of production.
13Harmonisation of standards?
- Differences in the abundance of environmental
resources and differences in the appetite of
populations for environmental quality make it
fairly clear that the harmonisation of
environmental standards is inappropriate. - There are perfectly legitimate reasons why
Governments should wish to set different
environmental standards.
14Impact of Regulation on Trade
- HO theorem predicts that tighter environmental
regulation at home leads to increased production
of environmentally intensive products abroad. - These environmentally intensive products are then
imported.
15Topical Example
- A single country or a bloc of countries imposes
restrictions on CO2 emissions. - This should result in an increase in CO2
emissions elsewhere, (carbon leakage). - Economists have utilised CGE models to estimate
the extent of carbon leakage associated with
attempts to reduce carbon emissions by, say, OECD
countries or the EU. - It is easy to understand why the threat of carbon
leakage might prompt policy makers to - (a) think about trade restrictions to prevent the
import of carbon intensive commodities and - (b) reconsider the wisdom of unilateral measures
to reduce carbon dioxide emissions.
16Other bases for trade in waste and residuals
- Differences in
- population density
- the waste assimilative capacity of countries
- national preferences for environmental quality
- also provide a basis for trade in waste and
residuals.
17Brief comments on some other theorems
18Stolper-Samuelson theorem
- The HO theorem explains why a country is able to
increase its income through trade. - But this does not mean that free trade will be
advantageous for everyone. - The Stolper-Samuelson theorem demonstrates that
those who supply the scarce factor of production
can gain through protection that restricts
imports of goods intensive in that factor. - A tariff will increase the income of the factor
used intensively in the good that receives
protection. - Intuition the resulting increase in the price
of the good increases the derived demand and
therefore the price of the intensively-employed
factor.
19Applicability of Stolper-Samuelson
- Many environmental resources are not privately
owned. - But where environmental resources are subject to
private property rights (perhaps because these
have been created by the Government in the form
of tradable permits) then the Stolper-Samuelson
theorem may apply.
20The Rybczynski theorem
- An increase in the endowment of one factor will
reduce the production of goods intensive in the
other factor. - For example, if there is an increase in labour
the production of capital intensive goods will
decline. - A de facto increase in environmental resources
caused for example by an increased allocation of
environmental permits by an incoming Government
that cares less for environmental quality should
decrease the production of environmentally
less-intensive commodities.
21The factor price equalisation theorem
- HO suggests that free trade would equalise factor
prices since a country would export goods
intensive in its abundant factor of production
and import goods intensive in its scare factor of
production. This would decrease the derived
demand for the scarce factor of production and
increase the demand for the abundant factor of
production thereby reducing international
differences in factor prices. - Despite the fact that there is much capital
mobility, and quite a lot of labour mobility,
observation suggests that factor price
equalisation does not hold. Unskilled workers in
the developed world continue to earn far more
than equivalent workers in Less Developed
Countries. This could be attributed to the rather
rigid assumptions upon which the theorem, and
indeed the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem, is based e.g.
the existence of free trade and the assumption
that production technologies are the same
everywhere. - The factor price equalisation theorem would seem
to suggest that international trade equalises the
shadow price of environmental resources a
striking result. The shadow price of
environmental resources means environmental tax
rates or the price of environmental permits. Note
that this does not require tax rate harmonisation
or trade in permits. This of course does not
mean that environmental quality will be
equalised.
2210.1.1 North-South models of trade and the
environment
- So-called North-South models suggest that the
source of the poor Souths advantage is not that
they have abundant environmental resources but
that the use of these resources is unregulated by
the Government. - Such models are associated with the seminal paper
of Chichilnisky (1994). This gives the South an
illusory comparative advantage in the production
of environmentally intensive goods. It is
customary to refer to the region suffering from
absent property rights governing access to the
environmental resource as the South and the
region in which property rights both exist, and
are enforced, as the North. - Due to the mismanagement of environmental
resources trade may exacerbate the environmental
problems of the South whilst the rich North
benefits from trade.
2310.2 Does free trade harm the environment? A
partial equilibrium analysis
- The preceding section extended classical theories
of trade to include environmental resources. - We will now address the twin questions of (a)
whether trade is bad for the environment and (b)
whether it matters in a partial equilibrium
setting in which the production of a single good
gives rise to external costs. - For the sake of simplicity these external costs
are assumed to arise from the production of the
good rather than the use of particular production
processes. - The country is assumed to be small such that it
cannot affect its own terms of trade. Factors of
production are assumed to be immobile and there
is no transboundary pollution.
24Cases to consider
- This analysis follows closely that of Anderson
(1992). - Assume that the country switches from an initial
position of autarky to one of free trade. - Four cases to consider
- the country already imposes ,and retains, an
(allocatively efficient) environmental tax or
permit quantity of the correct amount and becomes
a net importer - the country already imposes, and retains, an
environmental tax and becomes a net exporter - the country does not already impose, nor
introduces, an environmental tax and becomes net
importer - the country does not already impose, nor
introduces, an environmental tax and becomes net
exporter. - Liberalising trade in the good whose production
harms the environment can be welfare enhancing or
not depending upon whether the country already
imposes the efficient tax rate on domestic
production.
25Cases c) and d) efficient tax not imposed
- the country does not impose an environmental tax
and becomes net importer - the country does not impose an environmental tax
and becomes net exporter. - Begin with cases where the country does not
impose an efficient environmental tax, and trade
is liberalised in the good whose production harms
the environment. - If the good ends up being imported then welfare
is definitely improved. This is because real
resource costs fall whilst at the same time
domestic pollution levels fall.
26(No Transcript)
27(No Transcript)
28Case (d) Figure 10.2
- The horizontal line P is now higher, indicating
that opening up to trade will result in a higher
price for consumers and increased domestic
production leading to exports. - Production rises from Q to Qx whilst consumption
falls to Cx. The change in economic surplus is
given by eik although there is an increase in
environmental costs of dekm. - The relative size of these areas and therefore
the overall welfare impact is unclear. - Consequently if a country without environmental
taxes ends up being a net exporter then the gains
from trade may be more than outweighed by the
losses from increased production and the external
costs that this generates a situation of some
concern.
29Cases a) and b) efficient environmental tax
already imposed
- If the pollution tax is already in place when
trade is liberalised then benefits from trade are
secured irrespective of whether the final
position of the country is one of exporter or
importer. - For the case in which the good ends up being
imported, Figure 10.1 shows that the change in
welfare is qcf. - For the case in which the commodity ends up
being exported, Figure 10.2 shows that the change
in welfare is cij. - So even if production is increased to supply the
export market the benefits from trade more than
outweigh the monetised losses from increased
pollution.
30Is a pollution tax superior to a tax on exports
or a subsidy to imports as means of controlling
environmental problems?
- Suppose that rather than imposing an
environmental tax on pollution, a tax is instead
imposed on the exports of the polluting
commodity. This reduces the price faced by
domestic consumers of that commodity, meaning
that they will now purchase too much of the good.
More specifically, they value infra marginal
units of the good less than do foreign consumers.
Accordingly, whilst trade taxes and subsidies can
influence domestic pollution levels they do so by
imposing higher costs. - What happens to the small country when emissions
taxes are placed upon the production of an
environmentally damaging commodity in the rest of
the world? Does this increase or decrease the
benefits from free trade to the small open
economy? - If the country is already an exporter of the
commodity, Anderson shows that an increase in the
international price of the commodity increases
pollution levels in the small economy. However,
the benefits to the economy are always positive
if the correct tax on pollution is already in
place since the gains from trade always outweigh
the losses from more pollution. - If the appropriate tax is not already in place
there could be either benefits or disbenefits
since the quantity of pollution is already
excessive. - If, on the other hand, the country is an importer
and remains an importer then the gains from trade
are reduced. -
31Summary of the partial equilibrium analysis
- Free trade is better than no trade provided that
the requisite efficient environmental taxes, or
their equivalent, are in place provided, that
is, that the externality is efficiently
internalised. - Taxes or subsidies on trade could alter domestic
production levels and hence pollution but they
are inferior to taxing environmental pollution. - Countries have no incentive to depart from the
economically efficient level of tax placed on the
production of environmentally damaging goods. - What about the assumptions underlying the
analysis? - As developed countries raise their environmental
standards the production of environmentally
damaging goods will move to developing countries.
Eventually developing countries will become
exporters of environmentally damaging products.
But any further increases in international
standards will benefit developing countries. - The ability to import or export factors of
production assumed absent in the foregoing
discussion in response to changes in
environmental targets actually enhances the gains
from trade. - The assumption that pollution does not cross
national boundaries is important since with
transboundary pollution increases in pollution
affect all countries. Such transboundary
pollution would, however, occur even in the
absence of trade.
32Limitations of partial equilibrium models of
trade and the environment
-
- Partial equilibrium models are used for the
purposes of analysing the effects of liberalising
trade in one sector of the economy, when that
sector is small in relation to the rest of the
economy. - But there are important questions that a partial
equilibrium approach cannot answer. - What happens when trade is liberalised across
several sectors of the economy at once such that
the economy grows? - What happens to the shadow price of pollution?
- What happens to economy-wide emissions?
- Answering these and other questions requires a
general equilibrium approach in which all markets
clear simultaneously.
3310.3 General equilibrium models of trade and the
environment
-
- We show the derivation of a general equilibrium
level of pollution in an open economy as a
function of the general equilibrium marginal
abatement cost curve and marginal damage curves. - It goes on to consider the general equilibrium
effect of trade liberalisation on economic
welfare.
34The Copeland and Taylor Model
- Deals with a small open economy facing prices p
for two commodities x and y. - Production of commodity x results in pollution
and is referred to as the dirty good. - Production of good y produces no pollution and is
the clean good. - Economy has at its disposal L units of labour and
K units of capital. - Emissions are denoted z and are proportionate to
potential output of good x. - Emissions can be reduced by sacrificing some of
the output of good x. - Reducing emissions shifts the economys
production possibility frontier.
35Model Specification (1)
- The national income function G of the economy has
as its arguments world prices, the level of both
factor inputs, and permissible emissions -
-
- G returns the maximum value for national income
which can be achieved given prevailing world
prices, available factor inputs and production
technologies, and maximum allowable emissions. - Differentiating the national income function with
respect to emissions yields the general
equilibrium marginal abatement cost function. It
indicates by how much national income would
increase if emissions were allowed to rise by one
unit. - Associated with the general equilibrium marginal
abatement cost function is the marginal tax rate
t necessary to ensure that emissions do not
exceed z. -
-
36Model Specification (2)
- We turn now to the consumer side of the economy
in which there are N individuals. - The indirect utility function V of each
individual is given by -
- where IG/N is per capita income.
- The indirect utility function gives the maximum
amount of utility as a function of prevailing
prices, available income and emissions (which
impact negatively on utility).
37Deriving the Model Solution (1)
- The indirect utility function gives the maximum
amount of utility as a function of prevailing
prices, available income and emissions (which
impact negatively on utility). -
- This function is maximised subject to the
constraint linking national income to permitted
emissions.
38Deriving the Model Solution (2)
- The first order conditions include
- Given the assumption that world prices are wholly
independent of national emissions rearranging
equation 10.4 yields
39Deriving the Model Solution (3)
- The RHS of (10.5) is the Marginal Damage (MD)
from emissions. This will be a function of
prices, per capita income and emissions. - For optimality we already know aggregate marginal
damage should be set equal to the tax on
emissions so
40Deriving the Model Solution (4)
- The optimal level of emissions is therefore
implicitly defined by - The optimal level of emissions and the emissions
tax rate are jointly determined by the
intersection of the supply of emissions (i.e.
the aggregate marginal damage curve) and the
demand for emissions (i.e. the marginal
abatement cost curve).
41The Copeland and Taylor model and the EKC
- This framework can be used to trace out the
relationship between national income and
emissions the environmental Kuznets curve. - There is no straightforward relationship between
national income and emissions. - Both z and G are endogenous variables and the
precise relationship between national income and
emissions depends on what underlies the economic
growth. - If economic growth is caused by an accumulation
of human capital then the economy will
increasingly specialise in the labour intensive
non polluting commodity (Rybczynski T). Hence
demand for pollution falls whilst the growth in
income causes the supply of pollution to fall.
These effects are reinforcing gt a negative
relationship between economic growth and
emissions. - If growth in income is caused by an increase in
the capital stock then the demand for pollution
increases. This may be more than sufficient to
offset any income-induced reduction in the supply
of emissions gt positive relationship between
economic growth and emissions. - Economic growth first characterised by increased
capital and latterly by increased human capital
generates the stylised inverse U-shaped
relationship between income and emissions - the
EKC. But that is only one of many possible
outcomes.
42The effects of trade liberalisation
- What do CT mean by trade liberalisation?
- Trade liberalisation means either reducing the
level of some tariff which has been placed on
some imported commodity or alternatively, a
reduction in trade frictions. - In order to export a unit of a commodity an
amount (1?) units has to be shipped, where ?gt0.
This is known as the iceberg model for obvious
reasons. - This generates a real resource cost to
international trade representing perhaps, the
transportation costs of international trade.
43Trade Frictions
- Trade frictions create a difference between
foreign and domestic prices but do not result in
any Government revenue. - If the home country imports x the domestic price
will be pdp(1?) where p is the world price. - If x is exported then pdp/(1?).
- These frictions serve to reduce trade.
44Trade liberalisation key results due to Copeland
and Taylor
- If trade is distorted by the presence of trade
frictions, then trade liberalisation will
necessarily increase welfare providing that the
tax is set optimally. - C T demonstrate that the same analysis can also
be carried out when the trade distortion is in
the form of a tariff. - Once more, we see that if the pollution tax is
set optimally trade liberalisation would be
necessarily beneficial. - C T enquire further under what circumstances
the change in emissions will be positive or
negative as a result of trade liberalisation. But
irrespective of whether or not emissions increase
or decrease following trade liberalisation
provided that the tax on emissions has been set
optimally welfare is guaranteed to increase. - And if emissions are controlled via a system of
tradable permits then welfare necessarily
improves following trade liberalisation. - Trade liberalisation can therefore have quite
different consequences depending on whether the
country has a comparative advantage in the
production or the clean good, and depending on
whether environmental policy is optimally
adjusted, and if not what policy instruments are
used to control pollution.
45Scale, composition and technique effects
Grossman and Krueger (1993)
- G K give a useful decomposition for thinking
about the reasons underlying changes in
emissions. - Emissions are by definition equal to the overall
scale of activity S, multiplied by the share of
dirty goods in total output s, multiplied by the
emissions per unit of the dirty good, e. -
- Taking logarithms and then totally
differentiating this expression gives - This says that the percentage change in
emissions is equal to the percentage change in
the scale of output plus the percentage change in
the share of the dirty commodity plus the
percentage change in emissions intensity of the
dirty commodity.
46Reasoning which follows from this
- Trade liberalisation boosts market access which
will generate economic growth, so likely to lead
to an increase in the scale of economic activity.
- Other things being equal the scale effect will be
environmentally damaging. - Trade liberalisation is also likely to alter the
composition of output. - If a country enjoys a relative abundance of the
environmental factor of production then that
country will increasingly specialise in the
production of environmentally intensive dirty
commodities. - Similarly, if a country possesses a relative
abundance of capital then that country will
specialise in the production of capital intensive
commodities. In fact many goods are both capital
intensive and environmentally intensive. - The overall effect of the composition effect on
the environment is therefore ambiguous. - Insofar as trade liberalisation increases per
capita income levels the public will call for
greater environmental quality. - Assuming that the Government is responsive to
such demands it will tighten environmental
regulations. - Put another way, less of the environmental
resource will be allocated to production thereby
compelling producers to adopt different
production techniques. - This is the technique effect of trade
liberalisation. - The detrimental impact of trade liberalisation on
the scale effect, the ambiguous impact of trade
liberalisation on the composition of output
effect, and the likely beneficial impact of trade
liberalisation on the technique effect means that
the overall impact of trade liberalisation is an
empirical question.
47Box 10.1 The effect of trade liberalisation on
emissions An empirical test
- Cole and Elliott (2003) empirically analyse
(using panel data regression techniques ) the
effect of an increase in trade intensity (the
ratio of imports plus exports to GDP) on the per
capita emissions of four different pollutants
SO2, NOx, CO2 and Biological Oxygen Demand (BOD).
- An increase in trade intensity is taken as
synonymous with trade liberalisation. - With regards to the situation under autarky, Cole
and Elliott find that increases in the
capital-labour ratio increase per capita
emissions of SO2, NOx and CO2 although for SO2
each additional increase in the capital labour
ratio has a diminishing impact. For BOD, they
find no statistically significant relationship
between emissions and the capital-labour ratio.
The combined impact of the scale and technique
effects appears to be negative for SO2, positive
for NOx and CO2, and curvilinear for BOD. -
- The effects of an increase in trade intensity
depend on the relative value of the
capital-labour ratio. A high income country with
a high level of environmental regulations will
find that an increase in trade intensity
increases SO2 emissions. Nevertheless, a high
income country will experience falls in NOx and
BOD emissions in response to an increase in trade
intensity. - Cole and Elliotts findings for NOx and BOD are
quite different to those for SO2 and CO2. For
BOD, the trade intensity coefficient is negative
and significant, whilst for NOx it is positive
but insignificant. - With regards to SO2 emissions, an increase in
income of 1 percent will generate a reduction in
per capita emissions of 1.7 percent whereas the
trade intensity elasticity is 0.3 percent. The
results for BOD suggest that increased trade
intensity will reduce per capita emissions for
NOx and CO2 it is likely to increase emissions. - In an attempt to isolate the technique effect,
Cole and Elliott also estimate the impact of
changes in income and trade intensity on
emissions per unit of output. For all four
pollutants, growth in per capita income appears
to reduce the emissions intensity of output. The
trade intensity elasticity of emissions per unit
of output is either negative or statistically
insignificant.
48Do governments have an incentive to manipulate
environmental standards for trade purposes?
- Do governments distort their environmental
policies for trade purposes and if so what can or
should be done about it? - Environmentalists often express the concern that
Governments have an incentive to engage in
ecological dumping i.e. lowering environmental
standards in order to gain competitive advantage.
- This claim can be examined in the context of a
model of duopoly. - Analysis suggests that because international
trade agreements severely restrict the use of
more preferred policy instruments, policy makers
might strategically manipulate environmental
standards. - But, critically, policy makers sometimes have
incentives to adopt stronger rather than weaker
environmental standards. - In the context of a two-stage game Barrett (1994)
examines the incentives for Governments to behave
strategically whilst setting environmental
standards. - Production is assumed to generate environmental
emissions which cause localised environmental
damage even though such emissions may be abated
there are no transboundary pollution flows and
for convenience consumers are located in a third
country. - In the first stage of the game Governments choose
permissible emissions. In the second stage of the
game the firms choose their output. - Depending on the form of competition that ensues,
Governments have an incentive to set an
environmental policy that is either too weak or
too strong. - Whilst Governments have an incentive
strategically to manipulate environmental
standards, such a measure is always inferior to
conventional export subsidies or taxes. - Governments would always prefer using such
measures if they were permitted.
49Other results
- Brander and Spencer (1985), employing a similar
setup, find it optimal for Governments to
subsidise their own firms. - However, Barratt demonstrates that although the
Government is able to provide an implicit subsidy
by increasing the limit on emissions this has a
cost in the form domestic pollution problems. In
this sense it differs from a pure subsidy.
Consequently, a Government would prefer to use a
pure subsidy for the purpose of inducing a higher
level of output if only such a measure were
available to it. - The foreign Government would also respond
strategically. This gives the Nash response and
ironically both firms earn lower profits and
experience higher levels of pollution. However
neither country has the incentive to alter its
behaviour. Barratts paper further shows that
both countries have an interest in cooperating
and imposing and stronger environmental standards
than that corresponding to the environmentally
optimal emissions standard. - Although there is policy competition between the
two Governments this does not result in a race to
the bottom since there is a cost to Governments
engaged in an attempt to gain an increased share
of the world market in the form of increased
levels of domestic pollution. - Finally Barratt considers the case of Bertrand
competition where firms compete over prices
rather than output. The analytical model suggests
that Government should strategically reduce
permissible emissions. - Governments need to know the form of
oligopolistic interaction being used in the
market in which they want strategically to
intervene.
50Other results (2)
- How important are the assumptions of no domestic
consumers and no transboundary pollution flows to
this particular model? - Ulph (2000) explains that relaxing these
assumptions actually reinforces the conclusion
that Governments have incentives to engage in
ecological dumping. - Since imperfect competition implies less output
than socially desirable, Governments would
positively desire that their firms expand output.
Similarly, where there are transboundary
pollution problems Governments have an incentive
to reduce foreign output and hence foreign
pollution flows. - Do these arguments carry over to other kinds of
markets? There is no strategic element in
competitive markets since the world price cannot
be altered. In the monopoly case there is no
rival firm whose output can be manipulated. -
- There are however circumstances in which
Governments have incentives to manipulate the
terms of trade in their favour but, where
prevented from using export taxes and subsidies
for this purpose, manipulate environmental
standards as a second best. - For example, a country that is a major importer
of a polluting commodity will increase
permissible emissions to encourage domestic
production if unable to use an import tax to
depress world prices. Likewise a country which is
a major exporter of a dirty commodity will reduce
permissible emissions if it cannot use an export
tax to raise world prices.
51What can be done about Governments using
environmental policy for trade purposes?
- One possibility is to allow countries to take
action against those believed to be engaged in
environmental dumping. - However to substantiate such a claim it would be
necessary at the very least to demonstrate that
the standards are even lower than would be
expected on the basis of such factors as the
level of per capita income and the
characteristics of the physical environment.
Clearly that would be very difficult to do
(GATT, 1992). - Another possibility is to allow environmental
policy to be set at the supranational level e.g.
at the level of the EU. - What form might such intervention take?
- It is is very difficult to support the
harmonisation of biophysical standards and
environmental taxes. - Harmonisation is inappropriate because
environmental preferences differ as well as
differences in the ability of countries to
dissipate waste whereas minimum standards
presumes that if one country increases its
environmental standards to the required minimum
that another country is not then tempted to
reduce its own standards, standards that
currently exceed the minimum.
52Environmental policy and competition between
jurisdictions for mobile capital
- The view that national and regional Governments
are likely to compete to attract new firms in
part by relaxing environmental standards is
pervasive. - Numerous calls have been made for minimum
standards to prevent the excessive degradation of
environmental standards (e.g. Cumberland, 1981). - But what precisely are the incentives to engage
in a race to the bottom? - If residents care about environmental quality as
well as labour income then competitively lowering
environmental standards patently imposes a cost
on the community. - Indeed, rather than a race to the bottom arguably
we are witnessing the perpetual tightening of
environmental standards. - But is this the consequence of federal
Governments actively restricting the ability of
jurisdictions to use environmental regulation as
a tool to attract new businesses?
53Oates and Schwab (1984) model of
inter-jurisdictional competition
- In a community composed of homogeneous and
geographically immobile individuals, workers
select a tax rate on capital and simultaneously
the level of environmental quality. - Attracting capital boosts wages.
- But attracting capital via reducing taxes reduces
non-labour income, whilst attracting capital via
increasing permitted emissions reduces utility. - Model conclusions
- Only in very specific circumstances is there a
tendency for Governments to competitively lower
environmental standards. - And there are even circumstances in which
Governments might wish to competitively raise
standards.
54- Oates and Schwab then go on to consider the
situation in which the economy is populated by
heterogeneous individuals those who work and
those who rely on revenue from taxing capital. - Labourers would prefer an influx of capital that
will raise wages whereas non-workers want higher
capital tax revenues. - What happens depends on which group is in the
majority. If workers are in the majority then
there will be a subsidy to capital. Workers gain
the benefit of a larger capital stock in the form
of higher wages but bear only a fraction of the
cost of providing the subsidy. - To summarise, Governments have no incentive to
manipulate environmental standards in order to
attract capital unless they are obliged to tax
capital for revenue raising purposes. - In this case the marginal benefit of improving
the environment should exceed the marginal cost. - But in regions populated by heterogeneous
individuals this rule can be reversed.
55Banning trade in endangered species
- Measures to protect endangered species often
include banning international trade in animal
products e.g. skins and ivory, as well as better
enforcement of anti-poaching regulations and
compensation for preservation benefits enjoyed by
rich countries. - The 1973 Convention on International Trade in
Endangered Species (CITES) banned trade in animal
products listed in Appendix 1 to the agreement.
Trade in the animal products of species listed in
Appendix II to the agreement is also tightly
regulated. - The African elephant was added to Appendix 1 in
1989 following a serious decline in elephant
numbers during the 1970s and 1980s. Some sales of
ivory from stockpiles have nevertheless been
permitted. Since then elephant populations in
Eastern and Southern Africa have been steadily
increasing to the extent that South Africa is now
considering a culling program. According to the
IUCNs African Elephant Status Report 2007 there
are between 470,000 and 690,000 African elephants
in the wild. - Although adding the African elephant to Appendix
I has seemingly increased numbers, the following
question arises Does banning international trade
in endangered species like the African elephant
necessarily increase stocks?
56Does banning international trade in endangered
species like the African elephant necessarily
increase stocks?
- Addressed by the model of Bulte and Van Kooten
(1996). - Key finding is that the effect of a trade ban on
stock levels is ambiguous remain. - A key matter is the changed incentives of the
Government to limit the activities of poachers
under a trade ban. - There can be no presumption that banning trade
will necessarily increase the stock of an
endangered species. - At a minimum it is necessary to know about the
prevailing interest rate and the growth rate of
the species before recommending a trade ban.
57GATT and WTO
- The objective of the General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade (GATT) is the reduction of barriers to
international trade achieved through the gradual
elimination of tariffs, quantitative restrictions
and subsidies. - The GATT treaty was created in 1947 and lasted
until 1995 when it was subsumed into the World
Trade Organisation (WTO). - Discussing the lowering of tariffs is undertaken
in periodic rounds of negotiations frequently
extending over several years. Recent rounds have
dealt with amongst other things trade in
services, agricultural products and property
rights. - The latest of these, the Doha round, collapsed in
2008. - Amongst other things the WTO administers trade
agreements, serves as a forum for negotiations
and the resolution of disputes, monitors trade
policies, provides assistance to Less Developed
Countries and cooperates with other international
bodies. - The original GATT agreement contained a list of
38 articles of which the two most important are - the most favoured nation provision (Article I)
and - the national treatment provision (Article III).
- Under the GATT agreements, countries cannot
discriminate between trading partners. What this
means is that imports from any contracting party
should be treated no less favourably than like
products imported from any other contracting
party. Imported and locally produced goods should
be treated equally.
58GATT Article XX
- Deals with measures to protect human, animal or
plant life or health. - Extracts from text of GATT article XX
-
- Subject to the requirement that such measures
are not applied in a manner which would
constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
discrimination between countries where the same
conditions prevail, or a disguised restriction on
international trade, nothing in this agreement
shall be construed to prevent the adoption or
enforcement by any contracting party of measures - ...
- (b) necessary to protect human, animal or plant
life or health - ...
- (g) relating to the conservation of exhaustible
natural resources if such measures are made
effective in conjunction with restrictions on
domestic production or consumption - Source the WTO website http//www.wto.org/
59Tuna and dolphins
- A dispute between Mexico and the US over tuna
and dolphins has come to assume particular
importance in how many environmentalists view the
GATT and the WTO. - When tuna are fished using purse seine nets
dolphins can become unintentionally trapped and
suffocate. The US Marine Mammal Protection Act
(MMPA) sets out standards for the protection of
dolphins in the Eastern Tropical Pacific Ocean.
If a country exporting tuna to the US cannot
prove that its standards meet those enshrined in
US law then the US must embargo all imports of
tuna and tuna products from that country and any
intermediary countries that purchase tuna from
the country subject to the embargo. - The US embargoed tuna from Mexico, Venezuela and
Vanuatu, as well as a number of intermediary
countries because the methods used to catch the
tuna in these countries did not meet the
requirements of the MMPA. - In 1991 Mexico alleged that the US embargo on
their tuna exports was inconsistent with the
provisions of GATT. - The dispute settlement panel found that article
III requiring that imported products be accorded
a no less favourable treatment than domestic
products had indeed been violated. The US could
not curtail imports of tuna from Mexico simply
because the fishing method employed did not
satisfy regulators in the US. - The dispute settlement panel also declined to
uphold the embargo under article XX since
although the article dealt with measures
necessary to protect animals and exhaustible
natural resources this did not permit a country
to enforce measures falling outside its
territorial jurisdiction. - The argument of the dispute panel aimed to avoid
countries attempting to impose ethical standards
on other countries over which they have no
jurisdiction. - Although the US and Mexico ultimately decided to
settle their dispute bilaterally the tuna dolphin
case seemed to have troubling consequences. - Environmental impacts often cross national
boundaries. Surely a country can have a
legitimate interest in environmental events
occurring in areas outside its legal
jurisdiction? - Furthermore, the dispute resolution panel seemed
not to distinguish between environmental
resources which were not in the jurisdiction of
any state such as atmospheric or oceanic
resources, and those that were within the
jurisdiction of a state. The GATT secretariat
soon after made it explicitly clear that it was
not possible under GATT rules to make access to
ones own market dependent on the domestic
environmental policies or practices of the
exporting country.
60A critique of Article XX
- For a measure to be justified under Article XX it
must be first shown that it falls under at least
one of ten exceptions under Article XX of which
only (b) and (g) allude to the environment, and
then that the measure satisfies the introductory
paragraph (referred to as the chapeau of
Article XX), i.e. that it does not constitute a
means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
discrimination between countries where the same
conditions prevail and is not a disguised
restriction on international trade. - Article XX does not even use the word
environment. Likewise, article XX does not make
clear what it means by exhaustible natural
resources. Obviously, the GATT was drafted at a
time when the environment was not the priority
that it is today. - The insistence that Governments should employ
measures that are least inconsistent with GATT
policies is hard to understand. -
- The suggestion that scientific evidence is
required before a commodity can be restricted
even on a non-discriminatory fashion raises
further issues. - Environmentalists antipathy towards the GATT and
the WTO seems partly based on the belief that
trade causes environmental degradation and
competitive lowering of environmental standards.
But such beliefs might be misplaced. -
- GATT does not prevent countries from using market
based instruments or traditional command and
control techniques for the purposes of
environmental protection. Neither does the GATT
prevent a country from dealing with environmental
problems arising from goods whose production is
linked to environmental externalities whether
these goods are produced domestically or
imported. - The absence of any clause in Article XX allowing
trade sanctions to be used in the case of
pollution spillovers or degradation of the global
commons is troubling. - There is nevertheless, justifiable concern about
environmental issues being exploited by those
with protectionist motives. We have already
explained the risk that environmental regulations
will be used in place of the kind of exports
taxes and subsidies that the GATT has done so
much to combat.
61Summary (1)
- Basic trade theory suggests that countries will
specialise in those commodities that are
intensive in their most abundant factor of
production. Countries can be considered abundant
in environmental resources if they are sparsely
populated, possess environments capable of
dissipating environmental residues and have
populations that do not much care for
environmental quality, perhaps because of low
incomes. Such inter-country differences as exist
make it hard to sustain calls for the
harmonisation of environmental standards. - A partial equilibrium model suggests that trade
liberalisation could have a positive or negative
effect on the environment, but that even if it
did have a negative effect this might well be
outweighed by the real resource gains. And even
this could be avoided by imposing the appropriate
environmental tax from the outset. In a general
equilibrium model changes in trade frictions or
resource endowments cause changes in
environmental emissions. These can be usefully
decomposed into changes arising from the scale of
economic activity, changes in the composition of
output and changes in production technique. - It is possible to construct models in which there
are incentives to lower environmental standards
for trade purposes but this generally occurs
because countries are not allowed to use more
conventional measures. Depending on the precise
form that competition takes a country might even
have incentives to raise environmental standards.
Likewise there are circumstances in which
Governments might wish to lower environmental
standards in order to attract capital inflows.
This could occur if the Government is obliged to
tax capital. But there is an optimal degree of
relaxation involved and certainly no race to the
bottom.
62Summary (2)
- Banning trade in animal products may raise or
lower the stock of the species depending amongst
other things on the prevailing interest rate and
the species growth rate. - The GATT is required to deal with instances in
which calls for environmental protection have
protectionist motives. - Empirical studies have generally found little
evidence to suggest that patterns of trade are
determined by environmental standards in the
manner suggested by theory. - Although it might be correct in particular
instances, the belief that trade is bad for the
environment, that countries are forced to lower
environmental standards, that the WTO undermines
attempts to improve environmental quality and
that footloose firms exploit differences in
environmental regulations is not generally
correct.
63Discussion questions
- I think the economic logic behind dumping a load
of toxic waste in the lowest wage country is
impeccable and we should face up to that. Do you
think that the economic reasoning displayed here
is right or wrong? This is another quotation is
taken from an infamous memo allegedly written by
Lawrence Summers. The full memo can be found on
our website (as well as many other internet
sites). - Does international trade compel countries to
lower environmental standards? - Do you think that it is acceptable for the EU to
try to ban US beef containing growth hormones? Do
you think that such a manoeuvre would be
acceptable under GATT rules? - How would you test empirically the hypothesis
that differences in environmental regulations
provide a basis for trade? What difficulties
would you expect to encounter?