Trade and the Environment - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Trade and the Environment

Description:

Chapter 10 Trade and the Environment Unskilled labour in the EU, for example, has every incentive to lobby for protection on labour intensive goods from outside the EU. – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:121
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 64
Provided by: Rog885
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Trade and the Environment


1
Chapter 10
  • Trade and the Environment

2
Key Questions
  • What are the classical theorems of international
    trade and the implications of extending them to
    environmental resources?
  • When does trade liberalisation damage the
    environment and if so does it matter?
  • Do countries competitively reduce environmental
    standards and if so for what purpose?
  • Does banning trade in products made from
    endangered species necessarily augment stock
    size?
  • Does adherence to the General Agreement on
    Tariffs and Trade unduly constrain attempts to
    tackle environmental problems?
  • Does the empirical evidence suggest that
    differences in the stringency of environmental
    regulations are a major determinant of trade
    flows?

3
Viewpoints
  • Concerns expressed by environmentalists about
    international trade
  • Will gains from trade liberalisation be
    outweighed by the damage to the environment?
  • Is there an incentive for countries to engage in
    ecological dumping where one country lowers its
    emissions standards to gain some competitive
    advantage?
  • Will footloose industries migrate to pollution
    havens?
  • Will countries competitively lower environmental
    standards to generate trade benefits resulting in
    a race to the bottom?
  • What about the environmental impact of
    transporting goods internationally?
  •  
  • Businessmen often argue that environmental
    regulations
  •  will result in the loss of jobs, and that
  • the production of pollution intensive goods will
    merely be pushed offshore.
  • Politicians are concerned about the resulting
    unemployment.
  • Debate about the impact of international trade on
    the environment grew noisier in the early 1990s,
    mainly in response to fears about the possible
    impact of the proposed North American Free Trade
    Agreement (NAFTA) between Canada, the US and
    Mexico. Standing on a populist platform former US
    presidential candidate Ross Perot claimed that
    NAFTA would result in a giant sucking sound of
    jobs flowing to Mexico and recommended that
    Mexican goods be barred from entering the US
    unless they were produced under conditions
    meeting US standards for environmental
    protection. The exchange between Daly (1993) and
    Bhagwati (1993) is between two of the chief
    protagonists in the debate over NAFTA.
  •  

4
Debate
  • Debate about the impact of international trade on
    the environment grew noisier in the early 1990s
    ...
  • Mainly in response to fears about the possible
    impact of the proposed North American Free Trade
    Agreement (NAFTA) between Canada, the US and
    Mexico.
  • Former US presidential candidate Ross Perot
    claimed that NAFTA would result in large scale
    flow from USA to Mexico and recommended that
    Mexican goods be barred from entering the US
    unless they were produced under conditions
    meeting US standards for environmental
    protection.
  • The exchange between Daly (1993) and Bhagwati
    (1993) is between two of the chief protagonists
    in the debate over NAFTA.

5
Free Trade and Welfare
  • Many economists believe that free trade improves
    economic welfare.
  • Some welcome the fact that industries might wish
    to relocate in countries with low standards.
  • For them it just demonstrates that differing
    endowments are the basis of trade.
  • Economists do not generally accept the argument
    that countries ought to share the same
    environmental standards, given the existence of
    large differences in per capita incomes and
    population densities between countries.
  • Many economists therefore would see no reason for
    biophysical standards and environmental taxes to
    be harmonised.
  • Many would also contend that although changes in
    environmental regulation might result in
    temporary unemployment, changes in the exchange
    rate will ultimately restore the trade balance.
  • Calls for trade restrictions made on
    environmental grounds should be viewed with
    suspicion as they might be motivated by
    protectionist concerns.

6
Structure of this Chapter
  • Review of the traditional theory of trade
  • Extension of this theory to incorporate
    environmental resources.
  • Why might a country have an advantage in the
    production of environmentally intensive
    commodities.
  • Partial equilibrium analysis of the effects of
    moving from a position of autarky (no trade) to a
    system of free trade with and without the
    requisite controls on the production of
    environmental externalities.
  • We show that the problem is the absence of
    economically efficient environmental policy
    rather than trade liberalisation per se.
  • General equilibrium model analysis of the effect
    of trade liberalisation on welfare.
  • Consideration of situations in which governments
    might attempt to manipulate environmental
    standards in order to benefit national producers.
  • Development of a model in which jurisdictions
    compete in order to attract capital.
  • Is this likely to result in an erosion of
    environmental standards?
  •  The role played by the World Trade Organisation
    (WTO) in policing the global trading system.
  • What, according to the WTO, is the difference
    between justifiable and unjustifiable
    restrictions on trade enacted in the name of
    environmental protection?
  • Brief overview and critique of attempts to test
    the proposition that environmental regulations
    explain trade flows and patterns of Foreign
    Direct Investment (FDI).

7
Traditional trade theory
  • Traditional trade theory characterised by a
    number of theorems. These include
  • Heckscher-Olin theorem
  • Stolper-Samuelson theorem
  • Rybczinski theorem
  • Factor price equalisation theorem.
  • These are covered by any standard textbook on
    international trade e.g. Bhagwati and Srinivasan
    (1983).
  • Like Rauscher (1999) and Steininger (1999) we
    wish to consider the implications of these
    theorems when environmental factors of production
    are brought into the picture alongside capital
    and labour.
  •  

8
The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem
  •  
  • A fundamental proposition regarding the pattern
    of trade between two economies.
  • The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem suggests that trade
    is determined by differences in factor
    endowments.
  • A country will export those goods relatively
    intensive in its abundant factor of production
    and import those goods relatively intensive in
    its scarce factor of production.
  • For example, a country having an abundant supply
    of capital will find it cheaper to manufacture
    goods whose production is capital intensive.
  • The country is said to have a comparative
    advantage in the production of such goods.
  • Post free trade the consumption of the labour
    intensive goods will increase because of an
    increase in national income and a positive
    substitution effect whereas the consumption of
    capital intensive goods may or may not increase.
  • Taken as a whole, consumers unambiguously reach a
    higher level of welfare.

9
Heckscher-Ohlin theorem assumptions
  •  
  • The theorem rests on a number of assumptions
  • Countries have identical constant returns to
    scale technologies.
  • Countries have identical tastes.
  • There are no impediments to trade and no
    transport costs.
  • There are two goods, two factors of production
    available in fixed quantities, and two countries
    one of which is small and the other one large
    representing the rest of the world.
  • Factors of production are immobile.

10
Environmental extension (1)
  • How can the HO theorem be extended to include
    environmental and natural resources as factors of
    production?
  • The exports of many countries reflect their
    exploitation of particular natural resource
    endowments. But the observation that countries
    with, say, deposits of bauxite should
    specialise in the production of bauxite ore is
    not especially insightful.

11
Environmental extension (2)
  • But environmental resources include air, soil and
    water quality, and the capacity of the
    environment to assimilate the unwanted by
    products of economic activity.
  • From our perspective a country is therefore well
    endowed with environmental resources when it is
    sparsely populated and has a higher assimilative
    capacity.
  • HO theorem implies that countries well endowed
    with environmental resources should specialise on
    the production of environmentally damaging goods.

12
Endowment Regulation
  • Ultimately, a countrys endowment of
    environmental resources is determined by
    environmental regulation.
  • The stringency of environmental regulation should
    reflect the populations appetite for
    environmental quality.
  • The stringency of environmental policy is
    endogenous so the growth in income that
    accompanies trade liberalisation might increase
    the stringency of environmental policy and
    therefore reduce the endowment of environmental
    factors of production.

13
Harmonisation of standards?
  • Differences in the abundance of environmental
    resources and differences in the appetite of
    populations for environmental quality make it
    fairly clear that the harmonisation of
    environmental standards is inappropriate.
  • There are perfectly legitimate reasons why
    Governments should wish to set different
    environmental standards.

14
Impact of Regulation on Trade
  • HO theorem predicts that tighter environmental
    regulation at home leads to increased production
    of environmentally intensive products abroad.
  • These environmentally intensive products are then
    imported.

15
Topical Example
  • A single country or a bloc of countries imposes
    restrictions on CO2 emissions.
  • This should result in an increase in CO2
    emissions elsewhere, (carbon leakage).
  • Economists have utilised CGE models to estimate
    the extent of carbon leakage associated with
    attempts to reduce carbon emissions by, say, OECD
    countries or the EU.
  • It is easy to understand why the threat of carbon
    leakage might prompt policy makers to
  • (a) think about trade restrictions to prevent the
    import of carbon intensive commodities and
  • (b) reconsider the wisdom of unilateral measures
    to reduce carbon dioxide emissions.

16
Other bases for trade in waste and residuals
  • Differences in
  • population density
  • the waste assimilative capacity of countries
  • national preferences for environmental quality
  • also provide a basis for trade in waste and
    residuals.

17
Brief comments on some other theorems
18
Stolper-Samuelson theorem
  • The HO theorem explains why a country is able to
    increase its income through trade.
  • But this does not mean that free trade will be
    advantageous for everyone.
  • The Stolper-Samuelson theorem demonstrates that
    those who supply the scarce factor of production
    can gain through protection that restricts
    imports of goods intensive in that factor.
  • A tariff will increase the income of the factor
    used intensively in the good that receives
    protection.
  • Intuition the resulting increase in the price
    of the good increases the derived demand and
    therefore the price of the intensively-employed
    factor.

19
Applicability of Stolper-Samuelson
  • Many environmental resources are not privately
    owned.
  • But where environmental resources are subject to
    private property rights (perhaps because these
    have been created by the Government in the form
    of tradable permits) then the Stolper-Samuelson
    theorem may apply.

20
The Rybczynski theorem
  • An increase in the endowment of one factor will
    reduce the production of goods intensive in the
    other factor.
  • For example, if there is an increase in labour
    the production of capital intensive goods will
    decline.
  • A de facto increase in environmental resources
    caused for example by an increased allocation of
    environmental permits by an incoming Government
    that cares less for environmental quality should
    decrease the production of environmentally
    less-intensive commodities.

21
The factor price equalisation theorem
  • HO suggests that free trade would equalise factor
    prices since a country would export goods
    intensive in its abundant factor of production
    and import goods intensive in its scare factor of
    production. This would decrease the derived
    demand for the scarce factor of production and
    increase the demand for the abundant factor of
    production thereby reducing international
    differences in factor prices.
  • Despite the fact that there is much capital
    mobility, and quite a lot of labour mobility,
    observation suggests that factor price
    equalisation does not hold. Unskilled workers in
    the developed world continue to earn far more
    than equivalent workers in Less Developed
    Countries. This could be attributed to the rather
    rigid assumptions upon which the theorem, and
    indeed the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem, is based e.g.
    the existence of free trade and the assumption
    that production technologies are the same
    everywhere.
  • The factor price equalisation theorem would seem
    to suggest that international trade equalises the
    shadow price of environmental resources a
    striking result. The shadow price of
    environmental resources means environmental tax
    rates or the price of environmental permits. Note
    that this does not require tax rate harmonisation
    or trade in permits. This of course does not
    mean that environmental quality will be
    equalised.

22
10.1.1 North-South models of trade and the
environment
  • So-called North-South models suggest that the
    source of the poor Souths advantage is not that
    they have abundant environmental resources but
    that the use of these resources is unregulated by
    the Government.
  • Such models are associated with the seminal paper
    of Chichilnisky (1994). This gives the South an
    illusory comparative advantage in the production
    of environmentally intensive goods. It is
    customary to refer to the region suffering from
    absent property rights governing access to the
    environmental resource as the South and the
    region in which property rights both exist, and
    are enforced, as the North.
  • Due to the mismanagement of environmental
    resources trade may exacerbate the environmental
    problems of the South whilst the rich North
    benefits from trade.

23
10.2 Does free trade harm the environment? A
partial equilibrium analysis
  • The preceding section extended classical theories
    of trade to include environmental resources.
  • We will now address the twin questions of (a)
    whether trade is bad for the environment and (b)
    whether it matters in a partial equilibrium
    setting in which the production of a single good
    gives rise to external costs.
  • For the sake of simplicity these external costs
    are assumed to arise from the production of the
    good rather than the use of particular production
    processes.
  • The country is assumed to be small such that it
    cannot affect its own terms of trade. Factors of
    production are assumed to be immobile and there
    is no transboundary pollution.

24
Cases to consider
  • This analysis follows closely that of Anderson
    (1992).
  • Assume that the country switches from an initial
    position of autarky to one of free trade.
  • Four cases to consider
  • the country already imposes ,and retains, an
    (allocatively efficient) environmental tax or
    permit quantity of the correct amount and becomes
    a net importer
  • the country already imposes, and retains, an
    environmental tax and becomes a net exporter
  • the country does not already impose, nor
    introduces, an environmental tax and becomes net
    importer
  • the country does not already impose, nor
    introduces, an environmental tax and becomes net
    exporter.
  • Liberalising trade in the good whose production
    harms the environment can be welfare enhancing or
    not depending upon whether the country already
    imposes the efficient tax rate on domestic
    production.

25
Cases c) and d) efficient tax not imposed
  • the country does not impose an environmental tax
    and becomes net importer
  • the country does not impose an environmental tax
    and becomes net exporter.
  • Begin with cases where the country does not
    impose an efficient environmental tax, and trade
    is liberalised in the good whose production harms
    the environment.
  • If the good ends up being imported then welfare
    is definitely improved. This is because real
    resource costs fall whilst at the same time
    domestic pollution levels fall.

26
(No Transcript)
27
(No Transcript)
28
Case (d) Figure 10.2
  • The horizontal line P is now higher, indicating
    that opening up to trade will result in a higher
    price for consumers and increased domestic
    production leading to exports.
  • Production rises from Q to Qx whilst consumption
    falls to Cx. The change in economic surplus is
    given by eik although there is an increase in
    environmental costs of dekm.
  • The relative size of these areas and therefore
    the overall welfare impact is unclear.
  • Consequently if a country without environmental
    taxes ends up being a net exporter then the gains
    from trade may be more than outweighed by the
    losses from increased production and the external
    costs that this generates a situation of some
    concern.

29
Cases a) and b) efficient environmental tax
already imposed
  • If the pollution tax is already in place when
    trade is liberalised then benefits from trade are
    secured irrespective of whether the final
    position of the country is one of exporter or
    importer.
  • For the case in which the good ends up being
    imported, Figure 10.1 shows that the change in
    welfare is qcf.
  • For the case in which the commodity ends up
    being exported, Figure 10.2 shows that the change
    in welfare is cij.
  • So even if production is increased to supply the
    export market the benefits from trade more than
    outweigh the monetised losses from increased
    pollution.

30
Is a pollution tax superior to a tax on exports
or a subsidy to imports as means of controlling
environmental problems?
  • Suppose that rather than imposing an
    environmental tax on pollution, a tax is instead
    imposed on the exports of the polluting
    commodity. This reduces the price faced by
    domestic consumers of that commodity, meaning
    that they will now purchase too much of the good.
    More specifically, they value infra marginal
    units of the good less than do foreign consumers.
    Accordingly, whilst trade taxes and subsidies can
    influence domestic pollution levels they do so by
    imposing higher costs.
  • What happens to the small country when emissions
    taxes are placed upon the production of an
    environmentally damaging commodity in the rest of
    the world? Does this increase or decrease the
    benefits from free trade to the small open
    economy?
  • If the country is already an exporter of the
    commodity, Anderson shows that an increase in the
    international price of the commodity increases
    pollution levels in the small economy. However,
    the benefits to the economy are always positive
    if the correct tax on pollution is already in
    place since the gains from trade always outweigh
    the losses from more pollution.
  • If the appropriate tax is not already in place
    there could be either benefits or disbenefits
    since the quantity of pollution is already
    excessive.
  • If, on the other hand, the country is an importer
    and remains an importer then the gains from trade
    are reduced.
  •  

31
Summary of the partial equilibrium analysis
  • Free trade is better than no trade provided that
    the requisite efficient environmental taxes, or
    their equivalent, are in place provided, that
    is, that the externality is efficiently
    internalised.
  • Taxes or subsidies on trade could alter domestic
    production levels and hence pollution but they
    are inferior to taxing environmental pollution.
  • Countries have no incentive to depart from the
    economically efficient level of tax placed on the
    production of environmentally damaging goods.
  • What about the assumptions underlying the
    analysis?
  • As developed countries raise their environmental
    standards the production of environmentally
    damaging goods will move to developing countries.
    Eventually developing countries will become
    exporters of environmentally damaging products.
    But any further increases in international
    standards will benefit developing countries.
  • The ability to import or export factors of
    production assumed absent in the foregoing
    discussion in response to changes in
    environmental targets actually enhances the gains
    from trade.
  • The assumption that pollution does not cross
    national boundaries is important since with
    transboundary pollution increases in pollution
    affect all countries. Such transboundary
    pollution would, however, occur even in the
    absence of trade.

32
Limitations of partial equilibrium models of
trade and the environment
  •  
  • Partial equilibrium models are used for the
    purposes of analysing the effects of liberalising
    trade in one sector of the economy, when that
    sector is small in relation to the rest of the
    economy.
  • But there are important questions that a partial
    equilibrium approach cannot answer.
  • What happens when trade is liberalised across
    several sectors of the economy at once such that
    the economy grows?
  • What happens to the shadow price of pollution?
  • What happens to economy-wide emissions?
  • Answering these and other questions requires a
    general equilibrium approach in which all markets
    clear simultaneously.

33
10.3 General equilibrium models of trade and the
environment
  •   
  • We show the derivation of a general equilibrium
    level of pollution in an open economy as a
    function of the general equilibrium marginal
    abatement cost curve and marginal damage curves.
  • It goes on to consider the general equilibrium
    effect of trade liberalisation on economic
    welfare.

34
The Copeland and Taylor Model
  • Deals with a small open economy facing prices p
    for two commodities x and y.
  • Production of commodity x results in pollution
    and is referred to as the dirty good.
  • Production of good y produces no pollution and is
    the clean good.
  • Economy has at its disposal L units of labour and
    K units of capital.
  • Emissions are denoted z and are proportionate to
    potential output of good x.
  • Emissions can be reduced by sacrificing some of
    the output of good x.
  • Reducing emissions shifts the economys
    production possibility frontier.

35
Model Specification (1)
  • The national income function G of the economy has
    as its arguments world prices, the level of both
    factor inputs, and permissible emissions
  •  
  • G returns the maximum value for national income
    which can be achieved given prevailing world
    prices, available factor inputs and production
    technologies, and maximum allowable emissions.
  • Differentiating the national income function with
    respect to emissions yields the general
    equilibrium marginal abatement cost function. It
    indicates by how much national income would
    increase if emissions were allowed to rise by one
    unit.
  • Associated with the general equilibrium marginal
    abatement cost function is the marginal tax rate
    t necessary to ensure that emissions do not
    exceed z.
  •  

36
Model Specification (2)
  • We turn now to the consumer side of the economy
    in which there are N individuals.
  •  The indirect utility function V of each
    individual is given by
  • where IG/N is per capita income.
  • The indirect utility function gives the maximum
    amount of utility as a function of prevailing
    prices, available income and emissions (which
    impact negatively on utility).

37
Deriving the Model Solution (1)
  • The indirect utility function gives the maximum
    amount of utility as a function of prevailing
    prices, available income and emissions (which
    impact negatively on utility).
  • This function is maximised subject to the
    constraint linking national income to permitted
    emissions.

38
Deriving the Model Solution (2)
  • The first order conditions include
  • Given the assumption that world prices are wholly
    independent of national emissions rearranging
    equation 10.4 yields

39
Deriving the Model Solution (3)
  • The RHS of (10.5) is the Marginal Damage (MD)
    from emissions. This will be a function of
    prices, per capita income and emissions.
  • For optimality we already know aggregate marginal
    damage should be set equal to the tax on
    emissions so

40
Deriving the Model Solution (4)
  • The optimal level of emissions is therefore
    implicitly defined by
  • The optimal level of emissions and the emissions
    tax rate are jointly determined by the
    intersection of the supply of emissions (i.e.
    the aggregate marginal damage curve) and the
    demand for emissions (i.e. the marginal
    abatement cost curve).

41
The Copeland and Taylor model and the EKC
  • This framework can be used to trace out the
    relationship between national income and
    emissions the environmental Kuznets curve.
  • There is no straightforward relationship between
    national income and emissions.
  • Both z and G are endogenous variables and the
    precise relationship between national income and
    emissions depends on what underlies the economic
    growth.
  •  If economic growth is caused by an accumulation
    of human capital then the economy will
    increasingly specialise in the labour intensive
    non polluting commodity (Rybczynski T). Hence
    demand for pollution falls whilst the growth in
    income causes the supply of pollution to fall.
    These effects are reinforcing gt a negative
    relationship between economic growth and
    emissions.
  • If growth in income is caused by an increase in
    the capital stock then the demand for pollution
    increases. This may be more than sufficient to
    offset any income-induced reduction in the supply
    of emissions gt positive relationship between
    economic growth and emissions.
  • Economic growth first characterised by increased
    capital and latterly by increased human capital
    generates the stylised inverse U-shaped
    relationship between income and emissions - the
    EKC. But that is only one of many possible
    outcomes.

42
The effects of trade liberalisation
  • What do CT mean by trade liberalisation?
  • Trade liberalisation means either reducing the
    level of some tariff which has been placed on
    some imported commodity or alternatively, a
    reduction in trade frictions.
  • In order to export a unit of a commodity an
    amount (1?) units has to be shipped, where ?gt0.
    This is known as the iceberg model for obvious
    reasons.
  • This generates a real resource cost to
    international trade representing perhaps, the
    transportation costs of international trade.

43
Trade Frictions
  • Trade frictions create a difference between
    foreign and domestic prices but do not result in
    any Government revenue.
  • If the home country imports x the domestic price
    will be pdp(1?) where p is the world price.
  • If x is exported then pdp/(1?).
  • These frictions serve to reduce trade.

44
Trade liberalisation key results due to Copeland
and Taylor
  • If trade is distorted by the presence of trade
    frictions, then trade liberalisation will
    necessarily increase welfare providing that the
    tax is set optimally.
  • C T demonstrate that the same analysis can also
    be carried out when the trade distortion is in
    the form of a tariff.
  • Once more, we see that if the pollution tax is
    set optimally trade liberalisation would be
    necessarily beneficial.
  • C T enquire further under what circumstances
    the change in emissions will be positive or
    negative as a result of trade liberalisation. But
    irrespective of whether or not emissions increase
    or decrease following trade liberalisation
    provided that the tax on emissions has been set
    optimally welfare is guaranteed to increase.
  • And if emissions are controlled via a system of
    tradable permits then welfare necessarily
    improves following trade liberalisation.
  • Trade liberalisation can therefore have quite
    different consequences depending on whether the
    country has a comparative advantage in the
    production or the clean good, and depending on
    whether environmental policy is optimally
    adjusted, and if not what policy instruments are
    used to control pollution.

45
Scale, composition and technique effects
Grossman and Krueger (1993)
  • G K give a useful decomposition for thinking
    about the reasons underlying changes in
    emissions.
  • Emissions are by definition equal to the overall
    scale of activity S, multiplied by the share of
    dirty goods in total output s, multiplied by the
    emissions per unit of the dirty good, e.
  • Taking logarithms and then totally
    differentiating this expression gives
  • This says that the percentage change in
    emissions is equal to the percentage change in
    the scale of output plus the percentage change in
    the share of the dirty commodity plus the
    percentage change in emissions intensity of the
    dirty commodity.

46
Reasoning which follows from this
  • Trade liberalisation boosts market access which
    will generate economic growth, so likely to lead
    to an increase in the scale of economic activity.
  • Other things being equal the scale effect will be
    environmentally damaging.
  • Trade liberalisation is also likely to alter the
    composition of output.
  • If a country enjoys a relative abundance of the
    environmental factor of production then that
    country will increasingly specialise in the
    production of environmentally intensive dirty
    commodities.
  • Similarly, if a country possesses a relative
    abundance of capital then that country will
    specialise in the production of capital intensive
    commodities. In fact many goods are both capital
    intensive and environmentally intensive.
  • The overall effect of the composition effect on
    the environment is therefore ambiguous.
  • Insofar as trade liberalisation increases per
    capita income levels the public will call for
    greater environmental quality.
  • Assuming that the Government is responsive to
    such demands it will tighten environmental
    regulations.
  • Put another way, less of the environmental
    resource will be allocated to production thereby
    compelling producers to adopt different
    production techniques.
  • This is the technique effect of trade
    liberalisation.
  • The detrimental impact of trade liberalisation on
    the scale effect, the ambiguous impact of trade
    liberalisation on the composition of output
    effect, and the likely beneficial impact of trade
    liberalisation on the technique effect means that
    the overall impact of trade liberalisation is an
    empirical question.

47
Box 10.1 The effect of trade liberalisation on
emissions An empirical test 
  • Cole and Elliott (2003) empirically analyse
    (using panel data regression techniques ) the
    effect of an increase in trade intensity (the
    ratio of imports plus exports to GDP) on the per
    capita emissions of four different pollutants
    SO2, NOx, CO2 and Biological Oxygen Demand (BOD).
  • An increase in trade intensity is taken as
    synonymous with trade liberalisation.
  • With regards to the situation under autarky, Cole
    and Elliott find that increases in the
    capital-labour ratio increase per capita
    emissions of SO2, NOx and CO2 although for SO2
    each additional increase in the capital labour
    ratio has a diminishing impact. For BOD, they
    find no statistically significant relationship
    between emissions and the capital-labour ratio.
    The combined impact of the scale and technique
    effects appears to be negative for SO2, positive
    for NOx and CO2, and curvilinear for BOD.
  •  
  • The effects of an increase in trade intensity
    depend on the relative value of the
    capital-labour ratio. A high income country with
    a high level of environmental regulations will
    find that an increase in trade intensity
    increases SO2 emissions. Nevertheless, a high
    income country will experience falls in NOx and
    BOD emissions in response to an increase in trade
    intensity.
  • Cole and Elliotts findings for NOx and BOD are
    quite different to those for SO2 and CO2. For
    BOD, the trade intensity coefficient is negative
    and significant, whilst for NOx it is positive
    but insignificant.
  • With regards to SO2 emissions, an increase in
    income of 1 percent will generate a reduction in
    per capita emissions of 1.7 percent whereas the
    trade intensity elasticity is 0.3 percent. The
    results for BOD suggest that increased trade
    intensity will reduce per capita emissions for
    NOx and CO2 it is likely to increase emissions.
  • In an attempt to isolate the technique effect,
    Cole and Elliott also estimate the impact of
    changes in income and trade intensity on
    emissions per unit of output. For all four
    pollutants, growth in per capita income appears
    to reduce the emissions intensity of output. The
    trade intensity elasticity of emissions per unit
    of output is either negative or statistically
    insignificant.

48
Do governments have an incentive to manipulate
environmental standards for trade purposes?
  • Do governments distort their environmental
    policies for trade purposes and if so what can or
    should be done about it?
  • Environmentalists often express the concern that
    Governments have an incentive to engage in
    ecological dumping i.e. lowering environmental
    standards in order to gain competitive advantage.
  • This claim can be examined in the context of a
    model of duopoly.
  • Analysis suggests that because international
    trade agreements severely restrict the use of
    more preferred policy instruments, policy makers
    might strategically manipulate environmental
    standards.
  • But, critically, policy makers sometimes have
    incentives to adopt stronger rather than weaker
    environmental standards.
  • In the context of a two-stage game Barrett (1994)
    examines the incentives for Governments to behave
    strategically whilst setting environmental
    standards.
  • Production is assumed to generate environmental
    emissions which cause localised environmental
    damage even though such emissions may be abated
    there are no transboundary pollution flows and
    for convenience consumers are located in a third
    country.
  • In the first stage of the game Governments choose
    permissible emissions. In the second stage of the
    game the firms choose their output.
  • Depending on the form of competition that ensues,
    Governments have an incentive to set an
    environmental policy that is either too weak or
    too strong.
  • Whilst Governments have an incentive
    strategically to manipulate environmental
    standards, such a measure is always inferior to
    conventional export subsidies or taxes.
  • Governments would always prefer using such
    measures if they were permitted.

49
Other results
  • Brander and Spencer (1985), employing a similar
    setup, find it optimal for Governments to
    subsidise their own firms.
  • However, Barratt demonstrates that although the
    Government is able to provide an implicit subsidy
    by increasing the limit on emissions this has a
    cost in the form domestic pollution problems. In
    this sense it differs from a pure subsidy.
    Consequently, a Government would prefer to use a
    pure subsidy for the purpose of inducing a higher
    level of output if only such a measure were
    available to it.
  •  The foreign Government would also respond
    strategically. This gives the Nash response and
    ironically both firms earn lower profits and
    experience higher levels of pollution. However
    neither country has the incentive to alter its
    behaviour. Barratts paper further shows that
    both countries have an interest in cooperating
    and imposing and stronger environmental standards
    than that corresponding to the environmentally
    optimal emissions standard.
  • Although there is policy competition between the
    two Governments this does not result in a race to
    the bottom since there is a cost to Governments
    engaged in an attempt to gain an increased share
    of the world market in the form of increased
    levels of domestic pollution.
  • Finally Barratt considers the case of Bertrand
    competition where firms compete over prices
    rather than output. The analytical model suggests
    that Government should strategically reduce
    permissible emissions.
  • Governments need to know the form of
    oligopolistic interaction being used in the
    market in which they want strategically to
    intervene.

50
Other results (2)
  • How important are the assumptions of no domestic
    consumers and no transboundary pollution flows to
    this particular model?
  • Ulph (2000) explains that relaxing these
    assumptions actually reinforces the conclusion
    that Governments have incentives to engage in
    ecological dumping.
  • Since imperfect competition implies less output
    than socially desirable, Governments would
    positively desire that their firms expand output.
    Similarly, where there are transboundary
    pollution problems Governments have an incentive
    to reduce foreign output and hence foreign
    pollution flows.
  • Do these arguments carry over to other kinds of
    markets? There is no strategic element in
    competitive markets since the world price cannot
    be altered. In the monopoly case there is no
    rival firm whose output can be manipulated.
  •  
  • There are however circumstances in which
    Governments have incentives to manipulate the
    terms of trade in their favour but, where
    prevented from using export taxes and subsidies
    for this purpose, manipulate environmental
    standards as a second best.
  • For example, a country that is a major importer
    of a polluting commodity will increase
    permissible emissions to encourage domestic
    production if unable to use an import tax to
    depress world prices. Likewise a country which is
    a major exporter of a dirty commodity will reduce
    permissible emissions if it cannot use an export
    tax to raise world prices.

51
What can be done about Governments using
environmental policy for trade purposes?
  • One possibility is to allow countries to take
    action against those believed to be engaged in
    environmental dumping.
  • However to substantiate such a claim it would be
    necessary at the very least to demonstrate that
    the standards are even lower than would be
    expected on the basis of such factors as the
    level of per capita income and the
    characteristics of the physical environment.
    Clearly that would be very difficult to do
    (GATT, 1992).
  • Another possibility is to allow environmental
    policy to be set at the supranational level e.g.
    at the level of the EU.
  • What form might such intervention take?
  • It is is very difficult to support the
    harmonisation of biophysical standards and
    environmental taxes.
  • Harmonisation is inappropriate because
    environmental preferences differ as well as
    differences in the ability of countries to
    dissipate waste whereas minimum standards
    presumes that if one country increases its
    environmental standards to the required minimum
    that another country is not then tempted to
    reduce its own standards, standards that
    currently exceed the minimum.

52
Environmental policy and competition between
jurisdictions for mobile capital
  • The view that national and regional Governments
    are likely to compete to attract new firms in
    part by relaxing environmental standards is
    pervasive.
  • Numerous calls have been made for minimum
    standards to prevent the excessive degradation of
    environmental standards (e.g. Cumberland, 1981).
  • But what precisely are the incentives to engage
    in a race to the bottom?
  • If residents care about environmental quality as
    well as labour income then competitively lowering
    environmental standards patently imposes a cost
    on the community.
  • Indeed, rather than a race to the bottom arguably
    we are witnessing the perpetual tightening of
    environmental standards.
  • But is this the consequence of federal
    Governments actively restricting the ability of
    jurisdictions to use environmental regulation as
    a tool to attract new businesses?

53
Oates and Schwab (1984) model of
inter-jurisdictional competition
  • In a community composed of homogeneous and
    geographically immobile individuals, workers
    select a tax rate on capital and simultaneously
    the level of environmental quality.
  • Attracting capital boosts wages.
  • But attracting capital via reducing taxes reduces
    non-labour income, whilst attracting capital via
    increasing permitted emissions reduces utility.
  • Model conclusions
  • Only in very specific circumstances is there a
    tendency for Governments to competitively lower
    environmental standards.
  • And there are even circumstances in which
    Governments might wish to competitively raise
    standards.

54
  • Oates and Schwab then go on to consider the
    situation in which the economy is populated by
    heterogeneous individuals those who work and
    those who rely on revenue from taxing capital.
  • Labourers would prefer an influx of capital that
    will raise wages whereas non-workers want higher
    capital tax revenues.
  • What happens depends on which group is in the
    majority. If workers are in the majority then
    there will be a subsidy to capital. Workers gain
    the benefit of a larger capital stock in the form
    of higher wages but bear only a fraction of the
    cost of providing the subsidy.
  • To summarise, Governments have no incentive to
    manipulate environmental standards in order to
    attract capital unless they are obliged to tax
    capital for revenue raising purposes.
  • In this case the marginal benefit of improving
    the environment should exceed the marginal cost.
  • But in regions populated by heterogeneous
    individuals this rule can be reversed.

55
Banning trade in endangered species
  • Measures to protect endangered species often
    include banning international trade in animal
    products e.g. skins and ivory, as well as better
    enforcement of anti-poaching regulations and
    compensation for preservation benefits enjoyed by
    rich countries.
  • The 1973 Convention on International Trade in
    Endangered Species (CITES) banned trade in animal
    products listed in Appendix 1 to the agreement.
    Trade in the animal products of species listed in
    Appendix II to the agreement is also tightly
    regulated.
  • The African elephant was added to Appendix 1 in
    1989 following a serious decline in elephant
    numbers during the 1970s and 1980s. Some sales of
    ivory from stockpiles have nevertheless been
    permitted. Since then elephant populations in
    Eastern and Southern Africa have been steadily
    increasing to the extent that South Africa is now
    considering a culling program. According to the
    IUCNs African Elephant Status Report 2007 there
    are between 470,000 and 690,000 African elephants
    in the wild.
  • Although adding the African elephant to Appendix
    I has seemingly increased numbers, the following
    question arises Does banning international trade
    in endangered species like the African elephant
    necessarily increase stocks?

56
Does banning international trade in endangered
species like the African elephant necessarily
increase stocks?
  • Addressed by the model of Bulte and Van Kooten
    (1996).
  • Key finding is that the effect of a trade ban on
    stock levels is ambiguous remain.
  • A key matter is the changed incentives of the
    Government to limit the activities of poachers
    under a trade ban.
  • There can be no presumption that banning trade
    will necessarily increase the stock of an
    endangered species.
  • At a minimum it is necessary to know about the
    prevailing interest rate and the growth rate of
    the species before recommending a trade ban.

57
GATT and WTO
  • The objective of the General Agreement on Tariffs
    and Trade (GATT) is the reduction of barriers to
    international trade achieved through the gradual
    elimination of tariffs, quantitative restrictions
    and subsidies.
  • The GATT treaty was created in 1947 and lasted
    until 1995 when it was subsumed into the World
    Trade Organisation (WTO).
  • Discussing the lowering of tariffs is undertaken
    in periodic rounds of negotiations frequently
    extending over several years. Recent rounds have
    dealt with amongst other things trade in
    services, agricultural products and property
    rights.
  • The latest of these, the Doha round, collapsed in
    2008.
  • Amongst other things the WTO administers trade
    agreements, serves as a forum for negotiations
    and the resolution of disputes, monitors trade
    policies, provides assistance to Less Developed
    Countries and cooperates with other international
    bodies.
  • The original GATT agreement contained a list of
    38 articles of which the two most important are
  • the most favoured nation provision (Article I)
    and
  • the national treatment provision (Article III).
  • Under the GATT agreements, countries cannot
    discriminate between trading partners. What this
    means is that imports from any contracting party
    should be treated no less favourably than like
    products imported from any other contracting
    party. Imported and locally produced goods should
    be treated equally.

58
GATT Article XX
  • Deals with measures to protect human, animal or
    plant life or health.
  • Extracts from text of GATT article XX
  •  
  • Subject to the requirement that such measures
    are not applied in a manner which would
    constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
    discrimination between countries where the same
    conditions prevail, or a disguised restriction on
    international trade, nothing in this agreement
    shall be construed to prevent the adoption or
    enforcement by any contracting party of measures
  • ...
  • (b) necessary to protect human, animal or plant
    life or health
  • ...
  • (g) relating to the conservation of exhaustible
    natural resources if such measures are made
    effective in conjunction with restrictions on
    domestic production or consumption
  • Source the WTO website http//www.wto.org/

59
Tuna and dolphins
  •  A dispute between Mexico and the US over tuna
    and dolphins has come to assume particular
    importance in how many environmentalists view the
    GATT and the WTO.
  • When tuna are fished using purse seine nets
    dolphins can become unintentionally trapped and
    suffocate. The US Marine Mammal Protection Act
    (MMPA) sets out standards for the protection of
    dolphins in the Eastern Tropical Pacific Ocean.
    If a country exporting tuna to the US cannot
    prove that its standards meet those enshrined in
    US law then the US must embargo all imports of
    tuna and tuna products from that country and any
    intermediary countries that purchase tuna from
    the country subject to the embargo.
  • The US embargoed tuna from Mexico, Venezuela and
    Vanuatu, as well as a number of intermediary
    countries because the methods used to catch the
    tuna in these countries did not meet the
    requirements of the MMPA.
  • In 1991 Mexico alleged that the US embargo on
    their tuna exports was inconsistent with the
    provisions of GATT.
  • The dispute settlement panel found that article
    III requiring that imported products be accorded
    a no less favourable treatment than domestic
    products had indeed been violated. The US could
    not curtail imports of tuna from Mexico simply
    because the fishing method employed did not
    satisfy regulators in the US.
  • The dispute settlement panel also declined to
    uphold the embargo under article XX since
    although the article dealt with measures
    necessary to protect animals and exhaustible
    natural resources this did not permit a country
    to enforce measures falling outside its
    territorial jurisdiction.
  • The argument of the dispute panel aimed to avoid
    countries attempting to impose ethical standards
    on other countries over which they have no
    jurisdiction.
  • Although the US and Mexico ultimately decided to
    settle their dispute bilaterally the tuna dolphin
    case seemed to have troubling consequences.
  • Environmental impacts often cross national
    boundaries. Surely a country can have a
    legitimate interest in environmental events
    occurring in areas outside its legal
    jurisdiction?
  • Furthermore, the dispute resolution panel seemed
    not to distinguish between environmental
    resources which were not in the jurisdiction of
    any state such as atmospheric or oceanic
    resources, and those that were within the
    jurisdiction of a state. The GATT secretariat
    soon after made it explicitly clear that it was
    not possible under GATT rules to make access to
    ones own market dependent on the domestic
    environmental policies or practices of the
    exporting country.

60
A critique of Article XX
  • For a measure to be justified under Article XX it
    must be first shown that it falls under at least
    one of ten exceptions under Article XX of which
    only (b) and (g) allude to the environment, and
    then that the measure satisfies the introductory
    paragraph (referred to as the chapeau of
    Article XX), i.e. that it does not constitute a
    means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
    discrimination between countries where the same
    conditions prevail and is not a disguised
    restriction on international trade.
  • Article XX does not even use the word
    environment. Likewise, article XX does not make
    clear what it means by exhaustible natural
    resources. Obviously, the GATT was drafted at a
    time when the environment was not the priority
    that it is today.
  • The insistence that Governments should employ
    measures that are least inconsistent with GATT
    policies is hard to understand.
  •  
  • The suggestion that scientific evidence is
    required before a commodity can be restricted
    even on a non-discriminatory fashion raises
    further issues.
  • Environmentalists antipathy towards the GATT and
    the WTO seems partly based on the belief that
    trade causes environmental degradation and
    competitive lowering of environmental standards.
    But such beliefs might be misplaced.
  •  
  • GATT does not prevent countries from using market
    based instruments or traditional command and
    control techniques for the purposes of
    environmental protection. Neither does the GATT
    prevent a country from dealing with environmental
    problems arising from goods whose production is
    linked to environmental externalities whether
    these goods are produced domestically or
    imported.
  • The absence of any clause in Article XX allowing
    trade sanctions to be used in the case of
    pollution spillovers or degradation of the global
    commons is troubling.
  • There is nevertheless, justifiable concern about
    environmental issues being exploited by those
    with protectionist motives. We have already
    explained the risk that environmental regulations
    will be used in place of the kind of exports
    taxes and subsidies that the GATT has done so
    much to combat.

61
Summary (1)
  •  Basic trade theory suggests that countries will
    specialise in those commodities that are
    intensive in their most abundant factor of
    production. Countries can be considered abundant
    in environmental resources if they are sparsely
    populated, possess environments capable of
    dissipating environmental residues and have
    populations that do not much care for
    environmental quality, perhaps because of low
    incomes. Such inter-country differences as exist
    make it hard to sustain calls for the
    harmonisation of environmental standards.
  • A partial equilibrium model suggests that trade
    liberalisation could have a positive or negative
    effect on the environment, but that even if it
    did have a negative effect this might well be
    outweighed by the real resource gains. And even
    this could be avoided by imposing the appropriate
    environmental tax from the outset. In a general
    equilibrium model changes in trade frictions or
    resource endowments cause changes in
    environmental emissions. These can be usefully
    decomposed into changes arising from the scale of
    economic activity, changes in the composition of
    output and changes in production technique.
  • It is possible to construct models in which there
    are incentives to lower environmental standards
    for trade purposes but this generally occurs
    because countries are not allowed to use more
    conventional measures. Depending on the precise
    form that competition takes a country might even
    have incentives to raise environmental standards.
    Likewise there are circumstances in which
    Governments might wish to lower environmental
    standards in order to attract capital inflows.
    This could occur if the Government is obliged to
    tax capital. But there is an optimal degree of
    relaxation involved and certainly no race to the
    bottom.

62
Summary (2)
  • Banning trade in animal products may raise or
    lower the stock of the species depending amongst
    other things on the prevailing interest rate and
    the species growth rate.
  • The GATT is required to deal with instances in
    which calls for environmental protection have
    protectionist motives.
  • Empirical studies have generally found little
    evidence to suggest that patterns of trade are
    determined by environmental standards in the
    manner suggested by theory.
  • Although it might be correct in particular
    instances, the belief that trade is bad for the
    environment, that countries are forced to lower
    environmental standards, that the WTO undermines
    attempts to improve environmental quality and
    that footloose firms exploit differences in
    environmental regulations is not generally
    correct.  

63
Discussion questions
  • I think the economic logic behind dumping a load
    of toxic waste in the lowest wage country is
    impeccable and we should face up to that. Do you
    think that the economic reasoning displayed here
    is right or wrong? This is another quotation is
    taken from an infamous memo allegedly written by
    Lawrence Summers. The full memo can be found on
    our website (as well as many other internet
    sites).
  • Does international trade compel countries to
    lower environmental standards?
  • Do you think that it is acceptable for the EU to
    try to ban US beef containing growth hormones? Do
    you think that such a manoeuvre would be
    acceptable under GATT rules?
  • How would you test empirically the hypothesis
    that differences in environmental regulations
    provide a basis for trade? What difficulties
    would you expect to encounter?
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com