Title: Antti Punkka and Ahti Salo
1Incomplete Holistic Comparisons inValue Tree
Analysis
- Antti Punkka and Ahti Salo
- Systems Analysis Laboratory
- Helsinki University of Technology
- P.O. Box 1100, 02015 HUT, Finland
- http//www.sal.hut.fi/
2Value tree analysis
Overall goal (a0)
Attribute 1(a1)
Attribute 5(a5)
Attribute 4(a4)
Attribute 3(a3)
Attribute 2(a2)
Alternative 1 (x1)
Alternative 3 (x3)
Alternative 2 (x2)
3Value tree analysis
- m alternatives, Xx1,,xm , n attributes,
Aa1,,an - Additive value function
- Least and most preferred achievement levels
- all attributes relevant
-
- attribute weight wi represents the improvement in
overall value when an alternatives achievement
with regard to attribute ai changes from the
least to the most preferred level -
4Weight elicitation
- Complete information
- captured by point estimates
- e.g., SMART (Edwards 1977)
- Incomplete information
- weight and weight ratio intervals
- e.g.,
- e.g., PAIRS (Salo and Hämäläinen 1992), PRIME
(Salo and Hämäläinen 2001) - Ordinal information
- ask the DM to rank the attributes in terms of
importance - e.g., rank sum weights (Stillwell et al. 1981)
- incomplete ordinal information (RICH Salo and
Punkka 2003)
5Incomplete information
- Complete information may be hard to acquire
- alternatives and their impacts?
- relative importance of attributes?
- e.g.,
- Alternatives overall values can be represented
as intervals - e.g., the smallest and the largest possible value
can be solved through LP
where S is the feasible region for the attribute
weights based on the DMs preference statements
6Pairwise dominance
- Alternative xk dominates xj in the sense of
pairwise dominance - dominated alternative is non-optimal whenever the
DMs preference statements are fulfilled gt it
can be discarded - e.g., a problem with two attributes,
- Alternatives may remain non-dominated, however
- decision rules assist the DM in selection of the
most preferred one
where S is the feasible region for scores and
weights
7Decision rules
- Maximax
- alternative with greatest maximum overall value
- Maximin
- alternative with greatest minimum overall value
- Minimax regret
- alternative for which the greatest possible loss
of value against some other alternative is the
smallest - Central values
- alternative with greatest sum of maximum and
minimum overall value
8Use of ordinal preference statements
- Complete ordinal information
- ask the DM to rank the attributes in terms of
importance - derive a representative weight vector from the
ranking - rank sum weights (Stillwell et al. 1981)
- rank reciprocal (Stillwell et al. 1981)
- rank-order centroid weights (Barron 1992)
- Incomplete ordinal preference information
- the DM may be unable to rank the attributes
- which is more important - economy or
environmental impacts
9Rank Inclusion in Criteria Hierarchies (RICH)
- Associate possible rankings with sets of
attributes - e.g., economy and environmental impacts are
among the three most important attributes - presumably easier and faster to give than
numerical statements - easy to understand
- statements define possibly non-convex feasible
regions - Supported by the decision support tool RICH
Decisions http//www.rich.hut.fi
The most important of the three attributes is
either attribute 1 or 2
10Ordinal information in evaluation of the
alternatives
- Numerical evaluation may be difficult
- may lead to erroneous approximations on
alternatives properties (Payne et al. 1993) - allow the DM to use incomplete ordinal
information - Score elicitation
- associate sets of rankings with sets of
alternatives - e.g., alternatives 1 and 2 are the two least
preferred with regard to environmental impacts - e.g., alternatives 3 and 4 are the two most
preferred with regard to environmental impacts
and cost together - rank two alternatives in relative terms
- e.g., alternative 1 is better than alternative 2
with regard to environmental impacts - can be subjected to
- all attributes (holistic comparisons)
- a (sub)set of attributes or a single attribute
11Incomplete holistic comparisons
- Evaluate some alternatives without decomposition
into subproblems - comparisons interpreted as (pairwise) dominance
relations - e.g., alternative x1 is better than alternative
x2 - e.g., alternative x4 is not the most preferred
one - Constraints on the feasible region
- e.g., normalized scores known
- three attributes
- alternative x1 is preferred to alternative x2
12Different forms of incomplete ordinal information
(Incomplete) ordinal information about
the importance of attributes (RICH)
(Incomplete) ordinal information about
alternatives, score information in form of
intervals
(Incomplete) holistic comparisons
LPs for 1) overall value intervals and 2)
pairwise dominance relations
Constraints on the feasible region
Decision recommendations
13Rank-orderings (1/2)
- Rank the alternatives subject to their properties
- the most preferred alternative has the ranking
one, etc. - e.g., alternatives x1, x2 and x3 ranked with
regard to cost r(r(x1), r(x2), r(x3))(1,2,3) - alternative x1 is the preferred to x2 which is
preferred to x3 - the alternative with a smaller rank with regard
to some attributes has greater sum of scores with
regard to these attributes - mathematically rAX is a bijection from X?X
onto 1,,m, Xm - Compatible rank-orderings
- I?X is a set of alternatives, J?1,,m a set
of rankings - if IltJ, the rankings of alternatives in I are
in J - if I?J , the rankings in J are attained by
alternatives in I - many compatible rank-orderings
- e.g., if m3, Ix1, J1 for Aa1, a2, then
compatible rank-orderings are rAX(1,2,3) and
(1,3,2).
14Rank-orderings (2/2)
- Feasible region associated with a rank-ordering
rAX convex - can be used as an elementary set
- R(I,J) contains the rank-orderings that are
compatible with the sets I and J - feasible regions defined by R(I,J) not
necessarily convex - Express statements as pairs of Ii, Ji, i1,,k
- feasible region is the intersection of the
corresponding S(Ii,Ji)s
15Efficiency of preference statements
- Monte Carlo study
- randomly generated problem instances (e.g.,
Barron and Barret 1994) - statements are based on them
- e.g., weight vector w(0.32, 0.60, 0.08)
approximated through the rank-ordering r(2,1,3) - correct choice, xC(i) at round i, (i.e., the
alternative with the highest overall value) can
be obtained - xe(i) is the alternative recommended by a
decision rule at round i - Measures
- expected loss of value (ELV)
- percentage of correct choices (PCC)
- average number of non-dominated alternatives
ns is the number of simulation rounds
nC is the number of problems where xe(i) xC(i)
16Efficiency of holistic comparisons
- Questions
- how effective are holistic comparisons?
- differences between strategies in choosing the
compared alternatives - Randomly generated problems
- n5,7,10 attributes m5,7,10,15,50 alternatives
- each weight vector has the same probability
- scores completely known, randomly generated
- uniform distribution, Uni0,1
- triangular distribution, Tri(0,1/2,1)
- Three strategies for choosing the alternatives
for pairwise comparisons - each applied in two different ways
- disconnected comparisons, x1 vs. x2, x3 vs. x4,
etc. - chained comparisons, x1 vs. x2, x2 vs. x3, etc.
17Simulation layout
- Elicitation strategies
- A. arrange the alternatives in a descending order
by the sum of the scores (strategies SoS1
(disconnected) and SoS2 (chained)) - B. arrange the alternatives in a descending order
by the score of the most important attribute
(strategies MIA1 and MIA2) - C. arrange the alternatives randomly (strategies
Rnd1 and Rnd2) - ELV and PCC was studied using central values,
maximax, maximin and minimax regret decision
rules - 100 problem instances (simulation rounds)
- several linear programs are needed
- results indicative
- parameter variation (m,n and the number of
comparisons) leads to 114 combinations,
experiments
18Simulation results (1/2)
- Sum of Scores is the best strategy
- SoS1 outperforms MIA1 in 113 of 114 experiments
in terms of ELV - in 82 of these the difference in loss of value
significant - risk level at 2.5 for a 1-tailed t-test
- SoS1 outperforms Rnd1 in every of the experiments
in terms of ELV - in 92 of these the difference in loss of value
significant - no clear difference between MIA1 and Rnd1
- Chained comparisons are better than disconnected
comparisons in terms of ELV and percentage of
correct choices
19Simulation results (2/2)
- Holistic comparisons reduce the number of
non-dominated alternatives efficiently - e.g., m50, n5, the average number of
non-dominated alternatives was between 3.92 and
9.17 with 10 comparisons, depending on the
strategy - e.g., m50, n5, with only one comparison the
average number of non-dominated alternatives was
between 20.57 and 23.69 - by discarding one alternative, an average of
almost 30 were eliminated - Triangularity assumption increases efficiency
20Conclusion
- Incomplete ordinal information enhances
possibilities in preference elicitation - presumably easier and faster to give than
numerical statements - easy to understand
- Screening of alternatives
- holistic comparisons efficient in discarding
non-optimal alternatives - useful especially in problems with many
alternatives - consequences of alternatives may be
time-consuming to obtain - constraints on the feasible region
- Further research directions
- efficient computational procedures
- simulation study on the efficiency of incomplete
holistic comparisons - implementation of a decision support system
- case studies
21Related references
- Barron, F. H., Selecting a Best Multiattribute
Alternative with Partial Information about
Attribute Weights, Acta Psychologica 80 (1992)
91-103. - Barron, F. H. and Barron, B. E., Decision
Quality using Ranked Attribute Weights,
Management Science 42 (1996) 1515-1523. - Edwards, W., How to Use Multiattribute Utility
Measurement for Social Decision Making, IEEE
Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics 7
(1977) 326-340. - Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R. and Johnson, E. J.,
The Adaptive Decision Maker, Cambridge
University Press, New York (1993). - Salo, A. ja R. P. Hämäläinen, "Preference
Assessment by Imprecise Ratio Statements,
Operations Research 40 (1992) 1053-1061. - Salo, A. and Hämäläinen, R. P., Preference
Ratios in Multiattribute Evaluation (PRIME) -
Elicitation and Decision Procedures under
Incomplete Information, IEEE Transactions on
Systems, Man, and Cybernetics 31 (2001) 533-545. - Salo, A. and Punkka, A., Rank Inclusion in
Criteria Hierarchies, (submitted manuscript
2003). - Stillwell, W. G., Seaver, D. A. and Edwards, W.,
A Comparison of Weight Approximation Techniques
in Multiattribute Utility Decision Making,
Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 28
(1981) 62-77.