Title: Optimal%20Taxation%20Theory%20and%20the%20Taxation%20of%20Housing
1Optimal Taxation Theory and the Taxation of
Housing
- Alan W. Evans
- Centre for Spatial and Real Estate Economics
University of Reading
2Optimal Taxation Theory
- Premise a government wishes to raise a given sum
through taxation but recognises that taxes
distort choice. - Question How should it raise this money if it
wishes to minimise the distortion which does
occur?
3Price
B
A
Supply curve with tax
E
D
Supply curve (perfectly elastic)
C
Quantity
F
G
O
The welfare loss (Atkinson Stiglitz, 1980)
4For Efficiency or Equity
- For Efficiency Impose taxes on goods with low
price elasticity, like housing - For Equity Impose taxes on goods with a high
income elasticity, unlike housing.
5A Survey of Recent Research
6Cremer and Gahravi (1998)
- They set out to explain housing subsidies for the
poor. - Subsidies are OK if poorer households can be
distinguished, and - If poorer households have a stronger preference
for lower quality housing than do wealthier
households
7So subsidies are a side issue, since the Cremer
and Gahravi result is not very policy
relevant. All other research relates to the
question of the separate tax treatment of owner
occupation and renting. Past research, going back
to Laidler (1969), suggests a welfare loss of a
half a percent or so, but this research uses
static models
8Skinner (1996)
- Argues dynamic effects are substantial.
- Uses an overlapping generations with bequests
model welfare loss of 2 - Low tax on o.o. causes price rise
- This results in a windfall gain to existing owner
occupiers. - The saving of younger generations is distorted
and goes into low taxed housing.
9Gervais (2002)
- Models a dynamic general equilibrium life cycle
economy. - Finds that low taxes encourage owner occupation,
and - Encourage owner occupiers to over-invest in
housing
10- Simulation (for U.S.) suggests
- Stock of business capital is 6 too low
- Stock of housing capital is 8 too high
11Englund (2003)
- Tax incentives encourage the young to buy early
- This results in a pattern of saving where savings
are high until they can buy, then low
(Englehardt, 2003) - The incentives also encourage taking on a high
risk which they should not.
12Eerola and Maattinen (2005)
- Taxes on owner occupied housing should be higher
than on business income, not lower - Firstly, the tax on imputed income from property,
and then - Secondly, an extra tax on housing as a good or
service (like VAT)
13The Problem of Land
- Land is not included in these models, it is
something where further research is needed.
14 Property Taxes in the USA
- These are ignored by researchers
- The justification is that they pay for benefits
- Therefore the two cancel out
- Research shows that taxes reduce property values
and benefits increase them - But at the margin?
- And with other tax systems?
15A Conclusion
- Property taxes are much higher in the US than in
most other countries. - Equal to about 1 of value. Differences like
Proposition 13 in California make it difficult to
generalise. - But US tax policy is more neutral than previous
researchers suggest.
16The UK Tax Neutrality
- Used to have a tax on the imputed income from
owner occupied housing, up to 1961. - Used to allow mortgage interest as a tax
deduction, but this was phased out between 1976
and 2000. - Gervais regards interest tax deductibility as the
main problem in the US
17Other Taxes Other Investment
- Capital Gains Tax Neutral, because of roll over
relief. - Stamp Duty (Transfer Tax) Neutral because small
and charged on both. - VAT Not charged on any residential property,
except extensions.
18Income Taxes
- Contributions to pension schemes have always been
tax deductible and for most this is their main
form of saving and investment. - Since the early nineties investment through PEPs
and then ISAs has been possible which is not
subject to income or capital gains tax. For all
but the wealthiest the amounts are substantial. - Does this help to ensure neutrality?
19Property Taxes in Britain
- The UK property tax (Council Tax) is not
proportional to capital value. - It is regressive, a high percentage on low value
dwellings, then lower. - It is effectively a fixed amount for dwellings
worth over about 1m
20The UK System
- The older and wealthier are favoured over the
poorer and younger - Although the younger may be paying mortgage
interest they are encouraged to buy and wait
until, after ten or twenty years mortgage
interest can be ignored - This is exacerbated by the implicit tax on land.
21Constraint
Price/Cost
D
T
D
A
A
O
S
Land
Constraint
22Or Tax
Price/Cost
D
T
D
Tax
A
A
O
S
Land
23The UK and Land
- House prices rise by 3.3 p.a. in real terms (W.
European average 1.8) - An implicit tax, paid by the younger generation
to the older - House construction is constrained
- New dwellings are smaller than in the rest of
western Europe England 76 sq.m., France 112.8
sq.m., Germany 109.2 sq.m. (Eurostat, 2002) -
24Commercial Land
- Taxed at a higher rate than residential land
- Extensive Uses (i.e. Manufacturing) Discouraged
- Intensive Uses (i.e. Offices) Encouraged
- Property Rented by Firms (possibly by Sale and
Lease Back), not owned
25Conclusions
- More research is needed on the role of land.
- In the UK land controls mean that there does not
seem to be overinvestment in housing. - Favourable tax treatment of savings helps in this
- But the market is distorted both by controls and
the Council Tax, and the latter is definitely not
an optimal tax. - There seems no reason why VAT should not be
imposed on new housing.