Title: Brand Name Prescription Drugs Antitrust Litigation 1999
1Brand Name Prescription Drugs Antitrust
Litigation (1999)
- Presented By
- Zhou Ge Stephen Stults
2Pharmaceutical Market
- 2003 US market value of US217.5 billion
- Accounts for 47 of world market
- 8.4 forecast annual growth rate 2003-2008
- Projected 2008 market value US325 billion
- (Datamonitor, Industry Profile Pharmaceuticals in
the United States, November 2004, datamonitor.com)
3History of the Industry
- Up to the 1970s the health care industry was
quite fragmented - Individual insurance companies would pay for
drugs on behalf of patients and had little
bargaining power with drug companies - Doctors decisions on what to prescribe were made
on a case by case basis
4History of the Industry
- Emergence of managed health care in late 1970s
concentrated buying power - Managed care providers would represent many
insurance companies when contracting patient
services and purchase of prescription drugs - Doctors now were limited to what they could
prescribe based on the rules of the health care
provider
5Formularies of Drugs
- A formulary is a list of prescription drugs
(established by a hospital or managed care
organization) that may be prescribed - Doctors can only prescribe drugs on this list
- Certain drugs can be given preferential status on
this list - Some drugs may even be given exclusive status for
a therapeutic class
6Increased Buying Power
- Managed care is able to exert greater bargaining
power as they - represent larger patient groups
- are able to influence doctors prescribing habits
based on status on formulary - can stimulate competition among drug
manufacturers for patients business
7Greater Concentration
- Percentage of privately insured population under
managed care - 1980 about 5
- 1987 about 25
- 1997 over 75
- Today about 170 million, or 65, of Americans are
covered by managed care providers - (Cutler and Sheiner, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Managed Care and the Growth of Medical
Expenditures, working paper 6140, August 1997)
8Distribution
- Distribution to managed care providers and retail
pharmacies are handled by drug wholesalers. - Discounts are given to managed care providers and
to other large buyer groups such as HMOs and
hospital groups. - Discounts are given in forms of chargeback, where
the manufacturer will pay the wholesalers back,
and through rebates.
9The Trial
10The Trial
- Retail drug stores claim that pharmaceutical
manufacturers - Price discriminate against retail drug stores
- (violation of Robinson-Patman Act)
- Conspired with distributors to refuse discounts
to retail drug stores - (violation of Section 1 of Sherman Act)
- Separate trials were scheduled for the violations
of the separate claims
11Some reach settlement
- The plaintiffs were some 40 thousand retail
pharmacies which were subsequently consolidated
into one class - 17 pharmaceutical manufacturers were being sued,
of which 11 chose to reach settlements totaling
US700 million - a defendant will settle if it believes that
- (Prob. of loosing x damages) legal fees
- is greater than settlement amount
12Conspiracy
- The charge of manufacturers and distributors
conspiring to refuse discounts to retail drug
stores was tried under the Sherman Act. - The Sherman Act requires that there be proof of
unlawful concerted action by all defendants. - The case went to trial in the fall of 1998.
13Focus of Trial
- Focus was on whether manufacturers colluded in
their refusal to extend the same price discounts
to retail drug store - Plaintiffs claimed that trade association
meetings provided opportunity for collusion - An opportunity for collusion relies on
speculation, and fails to prove that there was an
actual collusive agreement - Discounts arose out of defensive measures to
prevent lost sales in the managed care sector as
such buyers became more aggressive
14Status of Price discrimination Case
- Some of defendants have reach settlements with
plaintiffs - A trail has not be on schedule.
15PRICE DISCRIMINATION PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
- THE ROBINSON-PATMAN ISSUE
16- Conventional Robinson-Patman Act Case
-
- Buyers are in head-to-head competition but
some of them pay a higher price than their rivals
pay.
17- Plaintiffs Claim
- This is just their situation.
- Defendants Claim
- The favored consumers are not in head-to-head
competition with retail pharmacies. - As discussed earlier, retail pharmacies are
dispensing agents rather than intervention
agents.
18Defendants maintained
- Rebates and chargebacks should be viewed as
Functional Discounts payment for a marketing
function. - Their discount to managed care and hospital
consumers began as a defensive reaction, named
Meeting Competition.
19What is Functional Discounts?
- Different from the quantity discount
- Prescription drug discounts are paid for
intervening on a large scale in the prescription
process, not for dispensing large quantities of
prescription drugs.
20For example
- American Association of Retired Persons (AARP)
operates one of the largest mail-order
pharmacies. But, it did not receive rebates or
chargebacks because it does not control
prescription patterns.
21Supports to the discount interpretation-1
- If volume discount were granted to a large drag
store chain, this would not increase total sales
of any particular drug. Because retails, even
large chains, do not have formulary control.
22Supports to the discount interpretation-2
- The rebates and chargebacks were arrived at on
a contract-by-contract basis - one discount for listing a brand name
prescription drug on a formulary - A large discount for giving that drug preferred
status on a formulary - An even large discount for an explicit market
share achievement -
23Supports to the discount interpretation-3
- Retail pharmacies are offered discounts for
products where they are positioned to influence
the interbrand choices of consumers. - For example multisource drugs, over-the-counter
medicines and consumer medical products.
24What is Meeting Competition?
- Under the Robinson-Patman Act, a seller is
permitted to charge a lower price to one consumer
if the lower price is offered to meet the low
price of a competitor. This is called the
meeting competition defense to a charge of
price discrimination.
25How to check the meeting competition?-1
- We cannot simply to compare nominal price
- Because two offers with different nominal prices
may be viewed as equally attractive. - For example different price for different
quality lower price of new supply for switching
cost attractive price in order to meet the price
of bundle.
26How to check the meeting competition?-2
- In this case, it is offering a price low enough
to get on a formulary. - Because firms are profit maximizers, they do not
want to discount much more than to meet the
competition.
27Third Degree Price Discrimination, Prescription
Drugs, and Consumer Welfare
28- The manufacturers pricing practices are best
explained by the theory of third degree price
discrimination. - Retail pharmacies demand are less elastic
because they cannot maintain formularies or steer
prescriptions to particular drugs.
29Plaintiffs Discount
- Uniform pricing would cause all prices to fall to
the levels paid by the most favored customers. - Uniform pricing would increase aggregate economic
welfare.
30Defendants Discount
- Such a ruling would cause prices to seek a
higher, uniform level. - Uniform pricing would decrease aggregate economic
welfare.
31Why third degree price discrimination may
increase aggregate economic welfare?
32One reason
- Ramsey pricing principle In markets where scale
economies are so great that marginal cost pricing
is neither feasible or desirable,
welfare-maximizing prices in different segments
vary according to the inverse elasticity rule. - Danzon (1997) argued further, in the
pharmaceutical industry, scale economies lodged
in low marginal production costs and high, fixed
research and development costs. So, Ramsey
pricing is optimal. Price discrimination that
arise in competition are better than uniform
prices.
33Another reason
- More elastic managed care occurred, result in
discounts from the manufacturers. - The demand elasticity outside the managed cares
are not affected, so the discount paid to managed
care did not cause price increase for any
patient. - Price fall in one segment but did not rise in
another segment. The effect of discrimination
prices on aggregate economic welfare would be
positive.
34REFLECTIONS ON BNPDAL
35- The last quarter-century of antitrust has
stressed consumer welfare and economic efficiency
more than protecting small firms.
36Retail pharmacists problem
- Is not manufacturers refusal to discount, but
their own reluctance or inability to moving
market sharing.
37CONCLUSION
38CONCLUSION-1
- In the 1970s and 1980s, the price competition
is more intense. - The reason is
- Managed care organizations, along with
hospital and nursing homes, began to direct
groups of patients to particular firms to secure
lower prices.
39CONCLUSION-2
- Retail pharmacies, merely dispense the product
but do not prescribe or control its use. - The retails cannot leverage this competition to
their advantage.