Title: Decision Making
1Decision Making
- Jan Fidrmuc
- Brunel University
2Introduction
- Which decisions-making powers should be
transferred to the EU and which should remain in
the hands of national governments? - How much influence do national governments have
in the EU? - Can the EU make decisions effectively?
3Outline
- Distribution of Power and Subsidiarity
- Theory of Fiscal Federalism
- Qualified Majority Voting
- Efficiency of Decision Making
- Power Indices
4Distribution of Power and Subsidiarity
- Key question Which level of government should
be responsible for each task or policy
decisions? - Setting foreign policy
- Speed limits
- School curricula
- Trade policy
- Different levels of policy making
- Local, regional, national, EU
- Task allocation competencies in EU jargon
5Subsidiarity and Proportionality Principles
- Subsidiarity
- Decisions should be made as close to the people
as possible - EU should not take action unless doing so is more
effective than action taken at national, regional
or local level. - Proportionality
- EU should undertake only minimum action necessary
- Motivation to limit creeping competencies,
i.e. growing role of EU in policy making
63 Pillars and task allocation
- 3 Pillar structure delimits the allocation of
power. - 1st pillar Community (EU) jurisdiction.
- Single market issues, competition, trade
policies, monetary integration. - EU has final say, member states cannot opt out.
- 2nd and 3rd pillar national jurisdiction.
- Foreign/security policy, justice/home affairs.
- Members may pursue cooperation but are not bound
by EU decisions they disagree with. - Example Schengen Accord.
7Theory of Fiscal federalism
- Theoretical analysis can help determine whether
centralization or decentralization is optimal - Origins of the theory Power to tax
- Which taxes should be set at the national vs
sub-national level?
8Theory of Fiscal federalism
- Basic trade-offs
- Diversity and local informational advantage
- Scale economies
- Spillovers (externalities)
- Jurisdictional competition
- Democracy
9Diversity and Local Information
- Consider provision of a public good when regions
have different preferences (demand functions)
Region 1 values the public good less than Region
2. - Optimal quantity equates marginal cost and
marginal value of the public good - Under decentralization, local governments have an
information advantage and can implement optimal
allocations Qd1 and Qd2.
MCmarginal cost MVmarginal value
10Diversity and Local Information
- Centralization (one-size-fits-all policy) is
inefficient because it provides too much public
good for R1 and too little for R2. - Welfare loss of R 1 and 2 is area A and B,
respectively. - Examples
- Public transport,
- Schools,
- Language regime in a multi-lingual country.
11Economies of Scale
- Costs of providing public good may fall with
scale - E.g. single national rail or bus network may be
more efficient than many regional ones. - Different marginal costs apply in centralized and
decentralized case. - Region 1 welfare gain C vs loss D ?
centralization may be preferred. - National defense and foreign policy
12Spillovers
- Prisoners dilemma situations.
- Examples
- Environmental policies.
- Tax/VAT competition.
- If decentralised, each region chooses a level of
public good that is too low. - e.g. Qd2 for Region 2.
- Two-region gain from centralisation is area A.
- Similar conclusion with negative spillovers Q
too high under decentralization.
13Jurisdictional Competition
- Voters influence policies through
- Voice voting, party activism, protest, etc.
- Exit by moving to another region/country (voting
with your feet, Tiebout, JPE 1956) - Voting with ones feet common, especially at
sub-national level - Firms are particularly mobile and responsive to
local/national policies - Decentralization governments must deliver good
policies or risk losing tax payers - Centralization little possibility for exit
14Democracy as a Control Mechanism
- Politicians offer voters a package of policies
- Local government can offer package that better
reflects local needs - Decentralization gives voters better control over
policies - The same voter can support different parties in
national and local elections
15Summary
- Decentralization advantages
- Policies reflect local conditions and needs
- Voters have better democratic control over
policies - Centralization optimal when economies of scale
and/or spillovers are important. - 1st pillar (economy) large spillovers
- 2nd pillar (foreign/security policies) important
economies of scale but also large differences in
preferences across countries - 3rd pillar (justice/home affairs) intermediate
case moderate economies of scale and moderate
diversity in preferences
16Efficiency of decision making
- Fiscal federalism theory which decisions should
be made at the EU level - Focus now How does the EU make its decisions?
How likely is a decision-making gridlock? What
was the impact of enlargement? - e.g., Institutional changes in Constitutional/Lisb
on Treaty, Nice Treaty - Qualified majority voting (QMV)
- Enlargement-related institutional reform.
17Qualified Majority Voting
- Most EU decisions made by co-decision procedure
- Proposal adopted in the Council of Ministers by
QMV and in the EP by majority voting - Voting in the Council reflects States national
interests - QMV requires more than a simple majority to
approve a decision - This makes it easier for small Member States to
block decisions
18QMV History
- Before November 2004 Basic form unchanged since
the 1958 Treaty of Rome. - Post-2004 Nice Treaty QMV rules, unless replaced
by Lisbon Treaty rules. - Constitutional Treaty rules supposed to be
effective from 2009 but rejected in referenda in
France and the Netherlands. - Lisbon Treaty rules effective from 2014, or 2017
if delay requested by member states rejected in
referendum in Ireland
19Pre-2004 QMV
- Number of votes not perfectly proportional to
population - Total number of votes in the EU15 87
- Threshold for winning majority 62 votes
- ? qualified majority about 71 of votes
required to adopt proposal. - Relatively large coalition required to win a
vote. - Relatively small coalition of countries can block
a vote.
20Nice Treaty Reforms
- Two main changes
- 1. QMV rules more complex two new criteria in
addition to votes - votes 255 votes out of 345 Council votes in EU27
(74) - number of members half of the member states,
i.e. 14 out of 27 - population 62 of EU population.
- 2. Votes reallocated in favour of big nations
21(No Transcript)
22Nice-Treaty QMV Votes
23Constitutional Treaty
- Nice Treaty QMV rules relatively small coalition
can block important decisions. - Risk that Councils becomes deadlocked
- CT QMV rules proposal wins if backed by member
states with - At least 65 of EU population
- At least 55 of member states.
- At least 15 member states (irrelevant if the EU
has 27 or more members 15/2756) - Reallocation of vote shares large nations gain
(except Spain and Poland)
24Lisbon Treaty
- Lisbon QMV rules replicate CT rules
- Proposal wins if backed by member states with
- At least 65 of EU population
- At least 55 of member states.
- Unless replaced by Lisbon Treaty or another new
treaty, Nice Treaty rules remain in effect
25QMV Shadow Voting
- QMV is rarely actually used by the Council
- Most decision made by consensus
- Shadow voting
- If country knows it would be outvoted, it usually
joins the consensus - Otherwise, the vote does not take place to avoid
failure - QMV rules matter because they help countries
determine the likely outcome if vote were held
26EU Decision-making Efficiency
- Efficiency in decision making ability to reach
decisions - Voting rules and thresholds required to accept a
proposal are crucial - Formal Measures
- Passage Probability.
- Blocking coalition analysis
- Normalised Banzhaf Index.
- Many others are possible
27Passage Probability
- The number of all possible winning coalitions
divided by the number of all possible coalitions. - E.g. almost 33 ths possible coalitions in EU15
- Over 33 million possible coalitions in EU25.
- Passage probability equals probability of winning
if all coalitions are equally likely. - i.e. if countries voting behavior is random
- Caveat very imperfect measure.
- Proposals and countries positions not random
- But useful to measure decision-making efficiency.
28Historical Passage Probabilities
- Source Baldwin Widgren (2005)
29Blocking-coalition analysis
- Ability of likely coalitions to block EU
decisions. - Less formal and easier to think about.
- Probably close to what EU leaders had in mind.
- Example Newcomers and Poor in EU27
- Newcomers 12 new member states
- Poor Newcomers4 cohesion members (ES, PT, GR
IE) - Poor exceed the Nice Treaty blocking thresholds
of votes and member states - Newcomers exceed the votes threshold only
30Example 2 blocking coalitions, Nice rules
Council-votes
threshold
Number-of-Members
threshold
31Normalized Banzhaf Index (NBI)
- Power to break a winning coalition
- NBI is Members share of swing votes
- Caveat NBI disregards issues such as
agenda-setting power, and again assumes voting
behavior is random
32Normalized Banzhaf Index
- Consider all possible random coalitions
- n voters number of possible coalitions is 2n.
- Example with 3 voters ABC
- Possible coalitions ABC, AB, AC, BC, A, B, C,
none - Compute the number of winning coalition in which
the voter/nation is pivotal, i.e. the coalition
would fail if the voter defects - BNI is the ratio of the number of coalitions in
which the voter/nation is pivotal over all
possible coalitions - BNI measures the probability that the voter is a
deal breaker
33Power measures Example
- Why use complicated formal power measures instead
of vote shares? - Simple example 3 voters, A, B C
- A 40 votes, B40 votes, C20 votes
- Need 50 of votes to win.
- All equally powerful!
- Suppose now the threshold rises to 80 votes.
- C loses all power.
34Distribution of power in the EU
- For EU15, NBI is very similar to share of Council
votes, so the distinction is not so important
35Do power measures matter?
36Do power measures matter?