Chapter 11: The Economics of Global Climate Change

1 / 133
About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter 11: The Economics of Global Climate Change

Description:

http://www.grida.no/publications/other/ipcc_sr/?src=/climate/ipcc/emission/ 050.htm ... Total surface water equiv. ... program: http://www. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:424
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 134
Provided by: steveh74

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter 11: The Economics of Global Climate Change


1
Chapter 11 The Economics of Global Climate Change
  • Professor Steven C. Hackett
  • Humboldt State University

2
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Overview
  • Science
  • Impacts
  • Economics
  • Kyoto Protocol
  • AB 32, WCI, RGGI, EU ETS

3
Global Climate Change - Science
  • What is the greenhouse effect and how does it
    work?

4
Global Climate Change - Science
5
Global Climate Change - Science
6
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Absorbed by land, oceans, and vegetation at the
    surface, the visible light is transformed into
    heat and re-radiates in the form of invisible
    infrared radiation. If that was all there was to
    the story, then during the day earth would heat
    up, but at night, all the accumulated energy
    would radiate back into space and the planet's
    surface temperature would fall far below zero
    very rapidly.

7
Global Climate Change - Science
  • The reason this doesn't happen is that earth's
    atmosphere contains molecules that absorb the
    heat and re-radiate the heat in all directions.
    This reduces the heat radiated out to space.
    Called 'greenhouse gases' because they serve to
    hold heat in like the glass walls of a
    greenhouse, these molecules are responsible for
    the fact that the earth enjoys temperatures
    suitable for our active and complex biosphere.

8
Global Climate Change - Science
What are greenhouse gases?
  • Carbon dioxide Released to the atmosphere when
    solid waste, fossil fuels (oil, natural gas, and
    coal), and wood and wood products are burned.
  • Methane Emitted during the production and
    transport of coal, natural gas, and oil. Methane
    emissions also result from the decomposition of
    organic wastes in municipal solid waste
    landfills, and the raising of livestock.

9
Global Climate Change - Science
Greenhouse gases, continued
  • Nitrous oxide Emitted during agricultural and
    industrial activities, as well as during
    combustion of solid waste and fossil fuels.
  • Very powerful greenhouse gases that are not
    naturally occurring include hydrofluorocarbons
    (HFCs), perfluorocarbons (PFCs), and sulfur
    hexafluoride (SF6), which are generated in a
    variety of industrial processes.

10
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Each greenhouse gas differs in its ability to
    absorb heat in the atmosphere. HFCs and PFCs are
    the most heat-absorbent. Methane traps over 21
    times more heat per molecule than carbon dioxide,
    and nitrous oxide absorbs 270 times more heat per
    molecule than carbon dioxide. Often, estimates of
    greenhouse gas emissions are presented in units
    of millions of metric tons of carbon equivalents
    (MMT of CO2e), which weights each gas by its GWP
    value, or Global Warming Potential.

11
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Carbon dioxide, water vapor, methane, nitrous
    oxide, and other greenhouse gases are all
    molecules composed of more than two component
    atoms, bound loosely enough together to be able
    to vibrate with the absorption of heat.

12
Global Climate Change - Science
  • The major components of the atmosphere (oxygen O2
    and nitrogen N2) are two-atom molecules too
    tightly bound together to vibrate and thus they
    do not absorb heat and contribute to the
    greenhouse effect.

13
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Carbon dioxide is one of the most important
    greenhouse gases. It consists of one carbon atom
    with an oxygen atom bonded to each side. When its
    atoms are bonded tightly together, the carbon
    dioxide molecule can absorb infrared radiation
    and the molecule starts to vibrate.

14
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Eventually, the vibrating molecule will emit the
    radiation again, and it will likely be absorbed
    by yet another greenhouse gas molecule. This
    absorption-emission-absorption cycle serves to
    keep the heat near the surface, effectively
    insulating the surface from the cold of space.

15
Global Climate Change - Science
16
Global Warming Potential and CO2e
17
Global Climate Change - Science
  • What has been the trend in atmospheric carbon
    dioxide concentrations?

18
Change in Greenhouse Gas Concentrations in the
Atmosphere
Source IPCC, 2007
19
GHG Emissions
  • How do greenhouse gas emissions in the US compare
    to other industrialized countries around the
    world?

20
Source EPA
21
Top GHG-Emitting Countries
22
Top 10 Global Energy Consumers
Source BP Statistical Review of World Energy,
2006.
23
CO2 Emissions Trends 2005 - 2030
Source IEA WEO, 2006
24
Global Climate Change - Science
  • What has been the observed relationship between
    atmospheric carbon dioxide concentrations and
    global average temperature?

25
Global Climate Change - Science
26
Global Temperature Anomalies
27
Global Temperature Anomalies
28
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) Natural millennial
    climate swings are associated with slow
    variations of the earths orbit induced by the
    gravity of other planets.

29
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) Precise measurement of
    ice age atmospheric gases from bubbles in the
    Antarctic and Greenland ice sheets indicates that
    the change of climate forcing (from these
    gases) between the ice age and the present was
    about 6.5 watts per square meter.

30
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) Anthropogenic effects
    now exceed the natural effects from orbital
    perturbations.

31
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) Because of the large
    capacity of the worlds oceans to absorb heat, it
    takes the earth about a century to approach a new
    thermal balance (radiation in radiation out)
    from a given amount of forcing, but re-set at a
    higher temperature.
  • Meanwhile, more forcings occur.

32
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) The net value of
    forcings since 1850 is 1.6 /- 1.0 watt per
    square meter.
  • The earth is out of energy balance by 0.5 to 1.0
    watts per m2 (more in than out), implying that
    even if no new greenhouse gases were emitted by
    human activity, the earths surface would warm by
    0.4 0.7 degrees C.

33
Global Climate Change - Science
  • Hansen (Sci. Am. Mar 04) The growth rate of
    greenhouse gas forcing has slowed since the
    1980s due to fewer chlorofluorocarbon emissions
    and a slower growth rate in methane emissions.
  • NOAA in 2004 found that CO2 concentrations in the
    atmosphere increased by 3 parts per million in
    2003, considerably faster than the average rate
    of 1.8 ppm over the past decade.

34
Global Climate Change - Science
  • If current trends continue, what will happen to
    atmospheric carbon dioxide concentrations, and
    how might that affect global average temperatures?

35
Global Climate Change - Science
  • If nothing is done to slow greenhouse gas
    emissions
  • CO2 concentrations will likely be more than 700
    ppm by 2100
  • Global average temperatures projected to
    increase between 2.5 - 10.4F

36
Stern Review (2006) Trends
  • At current annual flow emissions rates, the stock
    of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere will reach
    double pre-industrial levels by 2050 - that is
    550ppm CO2e - and will continue growing
    thereafter.
  • But the annual flow of emissions is accelerating,
    as fast-growing economies invest in high carbon
    infrastructure and as demand for energy and
    transport increases around the world.
  • Thus the level of 550ppm CO2e could be reached
    before 2035. At this level there is at least a
    77 chance - and perhaps up to a 99 chance,
    depending on the climate model used - of a global
    average temperature rise exceeding 2C.

37
Stern Review (2006) Forecast
38
Stern Review (2006) Forecast
39
Global Climate Change - Science
  • In April 2000 the Intergovernmental Panel on
    Climate Change stated "that there has been a
    discernible human influence on global climate."

40
Global Climate Change - Science
  • A warming trend of about 1F has been recorded
    since the late 19th century. The IPCC projects
    further global warming of 2.2-10F (1.4-5.8C) by
    the year 2100. This range results from
    uncertainties in greenhouse gas emissions, the
    possible cooling effects of atmospheric particles
    such as sulfates, and the climate's response to
    changes in the atmosphere.

41
Global Climate Change - Science
  • The IPCC states that even the low end of this
    warming projection "would probably be greater
    than any seen in the last 10,000 years, but the
    actual annual to decadal changes would include
    considerable natural variability."

42
Sectoral Emissions
  • What are greenhouse gas emissions by sector?

43
Global Climate Change - Science
44
US Greenhouse Gas Emissions by Sector
45
Global Climate Change - Science
  • For the last 150 years or so, approximately 20 to
    25 percent of the increase in atmospheric carbon
    dioxide concentrations have come from changes in
    land use.
  • Examples include the clearing of forests and the
    cultivation of soil for agriculture.

46
Global Climate Change - Science
  • When forests are cleared and cultivated, some
    carbon stored in the woody matter of the trees is
    emitted immediately due to burning. Other carbon
    is released more slowly due to decay.

47
Global Climate Change - Science
What are carbon dioxide sinks?
  • Oceans (phytoplankton, coral reefs, other sea
    plants and animals)
  • Land sequestration in trees, soil, etc.

48
Global Climate Change - Science
  • According to the Woods Hole Research Center,
    about 100 Pg (one petagram 1 billion metric
    tons) of carbon (not carbon dioxide, which is
    much heavier) were released into the atmosphere
    from changes in land use world-wide between 1860
    and 1990.

49
Global Climate Change - Science
  • The annual emissions of carbon from changes in
    land use have been increasing, and by the late
    1980s stood at 1.6 Pg per year.

50
Kaya Identity
  • IPAT Impact Popul AffluenceTech
  • Kaya Identity (aka Kaya Equation), a more
    sophisticated version of IPAT
  • Anthropogenic
  • CO2 emissions E A x B x C x D

http//www.grida.no/publications/other/ipcc_sr/?sr
c/climate/ipcc/emission/050.htm
51
Kaya Identity
  • Kaya Identity E A x B x C x D, where
  • A Population.
  • B Per capita GDP (standard of living)
  • C Energy intensity (energy consumed per unit of
    GDP). Reflects energy efficiency and the
    sectorial make up of the economy.
  • D Carbon intensity (carbon emitted per unit of
    energy consumed). This quantity reflects the fuel
    mix of a given society.

52
Kaya Identity
  • Kaya Identity E A x B x C x D
  • Totally differentiating this equation yields
  • ?E ?A ?B ?C ?D
  • Where ? means percent change in

53
Kaya Identity
  • Kaya Identity ?E ?A ?B ?C ?D
  • Simply means that the percentage change in
    anthropogenic emissions equals the sum of the
    percentage changes in population, per-capita GDP,
    energy intensity, and carbon intensity.

54
Kaya Identity
Average Annual Percent Change 1980-1999
Source Tester et al. 2005. Sustainable Energy
Choosing Among Options (MIT Press)
55
Global Climate Change - Stabilization
Stern Report (2006) Stabilizing at or below
550ppm CO2e would require global emissions to
peak in the next 10 - 20 years, and then fall at
a rate of at least 1 - 3 per year. By 2050,
global emissions would need to be around 25
below current levels. These cuts will have to be
made in the context of a world economy in 2050
that may be 3 - 4 times larger than today - so
emissions per dollar of GDP would need to be just
one quarter of current levels by 2050.
56
IMPACTS Excerpts from Preparing for Change
Sept. 2002 Report by the California Regional
Assessment Group for the US Global Change
Research Program.
  • The number of threatened and endangered species
    in the state, already the largest in the
    contiguous 48 states, could rise significantly
    due these combined stresses. Extreme events, such
    as floods, droughts, and wildfires may become
    more frequent and intense.

57
Emissions Pathways, Climate Change, and Impacts
on California Katherine Hayhoe et al. 2004
(Proceedings of the Nat. Acad. Of Sci.)
  • Used two global climate models
  • NCAR/DoE Parallel Climate Model (PCM)
  • UK Hadley Centre Climate Model v. 3 (Had)
  • Applied a high emissions A (970 ppm) and a low
    emissions B (550 ppm) scenario, through 2100,
    drawn from the IPCC

58
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
  • Temperature
  • All simulations show increases in statewide
    annual average temperatures.
  • Avg. annual increase of 1.35 2 degrees C. by
    2050.
  • Avg. annual increase of 2.3 5.8 degrees C. by
    2100.
  • Summer temp. increases gt winter.

59
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
  • Precipitation
  • Three of four simulations project winter precip.
    decreases of 15 30 , with reductions
    concentrated on the North Coast and the Central
    Valley, by 2100.
  • These results differ from previous projections
    showing () precip.

60
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
Fig. 6. Winter (DJF) and summer (JJA) precip.
change for 2070-2099, relative to 1961-1990.
Geographical patterns of precipitation change are
consistent across models and scenarios, with the
greatest decreases occurring on the northwest
coast and along the eastern Central Valley and
western Sierras
61
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
  • Extreme Heat and Heat-Related Mortality
  • Temperature extremes increase in frequency and
    magnitude, with high emissions scenario A
    having the most dramatic increases.
  • Annual number of heatwave conditions days (3
    days of temp. gt 32 degrees C.) increases under
    all simulations.

62
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
Fig. 13. Change in number of days with heatwave
conditions occurring in Los Angeles, Sacramento,
Fresno and El Centro in 2070-2099 relative to the
1961-1990 average.
63
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
  • Impact on CA snowpack, runoff, and water supply
  • Rising temps less winter precip ? less
    snowpack.
  • Total surface water equiv. (SWE) losses by 2100
    range from 29-72 for low emissions scenario to
    73-89 for high emissions scenario.
  • Length, severity, and frequency of extreme
    droughts in the Sac R. system by 2100 increases
    substantially.
  • Near doubling in percentage of dry years (from
    32 historically to 50-64 by 2100)

64
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
Table 2. Percentage of years classified as wet,
above normal, below normal, dry, and critical for
the 19061996 historical period and simulated for
the years 20702099 for the Sacramento River
system (the 40-30-30 Four River Index)
65
Emissions Pathways/CA Impacts (2004), Cont
66
Global Climate Change Forecasts
Source IPCC, 2007
67
Forecasted Impacts Crop Yields
Source IPCC TAR
68
Risks Associated With from Global Warming
Source Parry (2001)
69
Economics Supply curve for liquid fossil fuels
Peak oil is a red herring a false message of
hope that we will run out of oil, thereby
restricting consumption and greenhouse gas
emissions from liquid fossil fuels.
70
Supply will not constrain consumption
Previous slide EOR Enhanced oil recovery GTL
Gas to liquid (i.e., convert natural gas to
liquid fuel) CTL Coal to liquid (i.e.,
Fischer-Tropsch Synthesis) The point of the
previous slide is that there is a very large,
upward-sloping supply curve of existing liquid
fossil fuels that go well beyond conventional
oil. Most of these imply much more carbon dioxide
emissions than conventional oil. Supply will not
constrain consumption we must use economic
instruments such as taxes or cap and trade to
limit consumption of liquid fossil fuels.
71
Liquid fossil fuels have big greenhouse gas
emissions
72
Economics
Estimated effect of different carbon charges on
the price-competitiveness of renewable energy.
Source EPRI, in NYT 07 Nov 2007.
73
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review (UK Govt sponsored
    independent report) on the economics of climate
    change
  • Examines the evidence on the economic impacts of
    climate change.
  • Explores the economics of stabilizing greenhouse
    gases in the atmosphere.

74
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review key finding
  • The benefits of strong, early action on climate
    change outweigh the costs.

75
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review key finding
  • It is not possible to predict the consequences
    of climate change with complete certainty, but
    enough is known to understand the risks.
  • Mitigation - taking strong action to reduce
    emissions should be viewed as an investment, a
    cost incurred now and in the coming few decades
    to avoid the risks of very severe consequences in
    the future.

76
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Ignoring climate change will eventually damage
    economic growth.
  • Our actions over the coming few decades could
    create risks of major disruption to economic and
    social activity, later in this century and in the
    next, on a scale similar to those associated with
    the great wars and the economic depression of the
    first half of the 20th century.
  • It will be difficult or impossible to reverse
    these changes.

77
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Climate change poses a grave threat to lower
    income countries due to
  • Geography (already in warm areas).
  • Ag dependent economies, and ag will be heavily
    impacted by climate change.
  • Lack money for mitigations.

78
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Climate change may initially have small positive
    effects for a few rich countries in high
    latitudes, but is likely to be very damaging for
    the much higher temperature increases expected by
    mid- to late-century under BAU scenarios.

79
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • With 5-6C warming - which is a real possibility
    for the next century - existing models that
    include the risk of abrupt and large-scale
    climate change estimate an average 5-10 loss in
    global GDP, with poor countries suffering costs
    in excess of 10 of GDP.

80
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Estimate that the total cost over the next two
    centuries of climate change associated under BAU
    emissions involves impacts and risks that are
    equivalent to an average reduction in global
    per-capita consumption of at least 5, now and
    forever.

81
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Including direct impacts on the environment and
    human health (non-market impacts) increases the
    estimate of the total cost of climate change on
    this path from 5 to 11 of global per-capita
    consumption.

82
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • A disproportionate share of the climate-change
    burden falls on poor regions of the world. If we
    weight this unequal burden appropriately, the
    estimated global cost of climate change at 5-6C
    warming could be more than one-quarter higher
    than without such weights.

83
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Estimates that the annual costs of stabilization
    at 500-550ppm CO2e to be around 1 of GDP by 2050
    - a level that is significant but manageable.

84
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Four ways to reduce emissions
  • Reduced demand for emissions-intensive goods and
    services
  • Increased efficiency, which can save both money
    and emissions

85
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Four ways to reduce emissions
  • Action on non-energy emissions, such as avoiding
    deforestation
  • Switching to lower-carbon technologies for power,
    heat and transport

86
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Studies by the International Energy Agency show
    that, by 2050, energy efficiency has the
    potential to be the biggest single source of
    emissions savings in the energy sector. This
    would have both environmental and economic
    benefits energy-efficiency measures cut waste
    and often save money.

87
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Action to prevent further deforestation would be
    relatively cheap compared with other types of
    mitigation.
  • The power sector around the world will have to
    be least 60, and perhaps as much as 75,
    decarbonized by 2050 to stabilize at or below
    550ppm CO2e.
  • Deep cuts in the transport sector are likely to
    be more difficult in the shorter term, but will
    ultimately be needed.

88
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • Estimates based on the likely costs of these
    methods of emissions reduction show that the
    annual costs of stabilizing at around 550ppm CO2e
    are likely to be around 1 of global GDP by 2050,
    with a range from 1 (net gains) to 3.5 of GDP.

89
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review detailed findings
  • This range of estimated costs was largely
    validated by macroeconomic modeling (the range of
    cost there was also centered on 1 of annual GDP,
    with a range of -2 (i.e., a benefit) to 5 of
    annual GDP).

90
Global Climate Change Economics
  • 2006 Stern Review critique
  • Many economists criticize the Stern Reviews use
    of a zero percent discount rate ie., valuing
    future impacts the same as today.

91
California Climate Risk and Response
Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
92
California Climate Risk and Response
  • Climate response mitigation to prevent the
    worst impacts and adaptation to climate change
    that is unavoidable on the other hand, can be
    executed for a fraction of these net costs by
    strategic deployment of existing resources for
    infrastructure renewal/replacement and
    significant private investments that would
    enhance both employment and productivity.

Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
93
California Climate Risk and Response
  • At the sector level, there will be some very
    significant adjustment challenges, requiring as
    much foresight and policy discipline as the state
    can mobilize. In this context, the political
    challenges may be much greater than the economic
    ones.
  • The states adaptation capacity depends upon
    flexibility, but divergence between public and
    private interests may limit this flexibility. As
    in the current financial dilemma, resolving this
    will require determined leadership.

Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
94
California Climate Risk and Response
  • Despite the extent and high quality of existing
    climate research reviewed in this document, the
    degree of uncertainty regarding many important
    adjustment challenges remains very high.
  • This uncertainly is costly, increasing the risk
    of both public and private mistakes and the
    deferral of necessary adaptation decisions.
  • Improving research and understanding of climate
    effects may itself be costly and difficult, but
    policymakers must have better visibility
    regarding climate risk and response options.

Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
95
Global Climate Change Economics
96
Global Climate Change Economics
  • According to a study by Burtraw and Toman (1998),
    climate change policy to reduce emissions of
    greenhouse gases (GHGs) may also reap
    environmental co-benefits by reducing emissions
    of other conventional pollutants.
  • These co-benefits, are realized immediately and
    could be on the order of 30 percent of the
    incremental cost of GHG reduction.

97
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • They evaluated the economic cost of Italy
    meeting the Kyoto Protocol (6.5 reduction in CO2
    by 2010).
  • They included in their analysis the current or
    co-benefits from reducing CO2 less sulfur
    dioxide, nitrogen oxides, carbon monoxide,
    mercury, etc., based on estimates of average
    external cost per unit of pollutant.

98
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • They identified the mix of fuel and energy
    sources that would meet Italys Kyoto target at
    minimum social cost.
  • In evaluating Italys current fuel mix versus
    the mix that meets the Kyoto target, they
    included avoided external costs to human health,
    agriculture, material goods, and ecosystems.

99
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • Based on an average global cost of 30 euros per
    ton of carbon dioxide, it would be advantageous
    economically for Italy to change its power
    generation strategy to comply with Kyoto.
    Scenario BAU Kyoto implies a 17 reduction in
    greenhouse gas emissions and 1800 x 106 in
    external cost savings, but a private cost
    increase of 300 x 106 to industry, yielding a net
    cost saving of 1500 x 106.

100
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • This is achieved with a fuel mix using more gas,
    less coal, more renewable sources, and more
    co-generation (combining electric and formerly
    waste thermal energy).
  • Implementing the MSC scenario would entail an
    even larger social cost savings, 2 billion euros
    per year.

101
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • Note Even if one totally excludes the 30 euros
    per ton of carbon dioxide from external cost,
    there is still a net social cost savings of 918 x
    106 per year, as the increase in private costs
    (548 x 106) is more than offset by the decrease
    in external cost (1466 x 106).

102
Global Climate Change Economics
  • De Leo et al. (Nature 413 478-79, 2001)
  • Conclusion Co-benefits of reducing local and
    regional air pollution and related external costs
    is a sufficient reason to cut the combustion of
    fuels responsible for global warming to the
    extent necessary to meet Kyoto targets for Italy.

103
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • In December 1997 the Third Conference of Parties
    adopted the Kyoto Protocol to the UN Framework
    Convention on Climate Change in Kyoto, Japan. The
    Kyoto Protocol commits Annex I Parties to
    individual, legally-binding targets to limit or
    reduce their greenhouse gas emissions, adding up
    to a total cut of at least 5 from 1990 levels in
    the period 2008-2012. The individual targets for
    Annex I Parties are listed in the Kyoto
    Protocol's Annex B, and range from an 8 percent
    cut for the European Union (EU) and several other
    countries, to a 10 percent increase for Iceland.

104
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • The rules for entry into force of the Kyoto
    Protocol require 55 Parties to the Convention to
    ratify (or approve, accept, or accede to) the
    Protocol, including Annex I Parties accounting
    for 55 of that groups carbon dioxide emissions
    in 1990.

105
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • 4 November 2004 -- President Vladimir Putin of
    Russia signed the federal law to ratify the Kyoto
    Protocol. This follows ratification of the
    Protocol by the State Duma (22 October) and the
    Federation Council (27 October). The Kyoto
    Protocol entered into force 90 days after
    Russia's instrument of ratification was received.

106
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • The Kyoto Protocol also establishes three
    incentive-based economic instruments that are
    designed to help Annex B countries reduce the
    cost of meeting their emissions targets. These
    instruments are joint implementation, emissions
    trading, and the clean development mechanism.
    These instruments allow Annex I countries to meet
    their emissions target by either producing or
    acquiring emissions reductions in other
    countries, most commonly lower-income developing
    countries.

107
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • In brief, Joint Implementation occurs when a
    donor country invests in pollution abatement
    measures in a host country in return for
    credits which it may use in meeting its own
    pollution abatement targets. In the Kyoto
    Protocol, JI occurs between Annex I countries
    (industrialized countries) that have emissions
    reduction targets.

108
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • The Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), where
    hosts do not have emissions targets (non-Annex I
    countries).

109
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • The Clean Development Mechanism was envisioned to
    perform a three-fold function
  • To assist non-Annex 1 countries in achieving
    sustainable development
  • To contribute to the ultimate goal of the
    convention i.e., stabilization of greenhouse gas
    concentrations in the atmosphere
  • To help Annex 1 countries comply with their
    emission reduction commitments.

110
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • Clean Development Mechanism (CDM)
  • Results in buyer receiving Certified Emissions
    Reductions (CERs) from the seller.

111
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • The International Rivers Network and CDM Watch
    produced a report in October 2002 on the use of
    hydropower projects in the CDM. The report
    Damming the CDM shows that big hydro
    threatens the effectiveness and credibility of
    the CDM, and risks undermining the entire Kyoto
    Protocol by providing carbon reduction credits
    for projects that dont actually reduce emissions.

112
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • Recent examples of CDM deals brokered by CO2e (a
    div. of Cantor)
  • Oct 04 Three sugarcane waste-fired electricity
    generation facilities in Brazil generated CERs
    to a European company that funded the facility
    through the CDM, for use in the EUs emission
    trading scheme (ETS).
  • Aug 04 A swine waste digester/methane
    combustion facility in Chile generated CERs to
    Canadian and Japanese utilities that funded the
    facility through the CDM. Reduced over 400,000
    tonnes of greenhouse gases reduced per year.

113
Global Climate Change Kyoto Protocol
  • Emissions Trading
  • The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme up
    and running in Jan. 2005
  • Mandatory emissions limits on all big
    industrial and energy intensive businesses by
    2005
  • These limits were too small too many carbon
    credits initially granted.
  • Exploring long-term rules for trading outside
    EU

114
Global Climate Change Economic Policies
  • The Stern Report (2006) suggests three economic
    policies are required to shift away from
    business-as-usual and stabilize carbon equivalent
    emissions

115
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • 1. Establishing a carbon price, either directly
    through a tax or through a cap-and-trade program,
    or indirectly through command-and-control
    regulation, is an essential foundation for
    climate-change policy.

116
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • A stable carbon price policy will be necessary
    for companies (and consumers) to invest in new
    more carbon-efficient products and technologies.
    And the knowledge gained from research and
    development is a public good companies may
    under-invest in projects with a big social payoff
    if they fear they will be unable to capture the
    full benefits. Thus there are good economic
    reasons to promote new technology directly.

117
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • There are likely to be high returns to a doubling
    of investments in this area to around 20 billion
    per annum globally, to support the development of
    a diverse portfolio of technologies.

118
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • 2. The second element of climate-change policy is
    technology policy, covering the full spectrum
    from research and development, to demonstration
    and early stage deployment.

119
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • 3. The third element is the removal of barriers
    to behavioral change. Even where measures to
    reduce emissions are cost-effective, there may be
    barriers preventing action. These include a lack
    of reliable information, transaction costs, and
    behavioral and organizational inertia. The impact
    of these barriers can be most clearly seen in the
    frequent failure to realize the potential for
    cost-effective energy efficiency measures.

120
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • Minimum efficiency standards for buildings and
    appliances have proved a cost-effective way to
    improve performance, where price signals alone
    may be too muted to have a significant impact.
  • Information policies, including labeling and the
    sharing of best practice, can help consumers and
    businesses make sound decisions.

121
Vehicle Energy Efficiency Standards
Source WRI, 2006
122
Stern Report Economic Policies
  • An effective response to climate change will
    depend on creating the conditions for
    international collective action.
  • Creating a broadly similar carbon price signal
    around the world, and using carbon finance to
    accelerate action in developing countries, are
    urgent priorities for international co-operation.

123
GHG Proposals in 110th Congress
124
Europe
  • The EU aims to commit itself, as part of an
    international climate protection agreement, to a
    30 reduction in its greenhouse gas emissions by
    2020 (compared with 1990).
  • Until a new agreement is concluded, and without
    prejudice to its position in international
    negotiations, the EU will reduce its emissions by
    at least 20 by 2020 (compared with 1990).

EU GHG Trends and Projections (1990 100)
125
EU Country Distance to Target
Source EU Environment Agency
126
Californias AB 32
The Global Warming Solutions Act (AB 32), which
was signed into law September 2006 and mandates a
first-in-the-nation limit on emissions that cause
global warming, requires that the California Air
Resources Board (CARB) put an implementation plan
(Scoping Plan) in place by January 2009.
Scoping Plan A policy roadmap to meet the
annual emissions reduction target of 169 Million
Metric Tons of Carbon equivalent (MMTCO2e) by
2020 to stabilize annual emissions at 427 MMTCO2e
overall.
127
Economic Impacts of Scoping Plan
Multiple studies have been conducted assessing
the economic impacts of CARBs Scoping Plan.
CARBs own economic analysis using the
Environmental Dynamic Revenue Assessment (E-DRAM)
model projects that the states proposed package
of policies will increase overall CA personal
income by 14 billion, overall gross state
product by 4 billion, and result in the creation
of 100,000 additional CA jobs.
Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
128
Economic Impacts of Scoping Plan
Using the Berkeley Energy and Resources (BEAR)
Model, we find that if California improves energy
efficiency by just 1 percent per year, proposed
state climate policies will increase the Gross
State Product (GSP) by approximately 76 billion,
increase real household incomes by up to 48
billion and create as many as 403,000 new jobs.
Fredrich Kahrl and David Roland-Holst, Dept Ag
and NR Econ Research Paper No. 08102801,
UC-Berkeley, Nov 2008
129
AB 32 and Regional Partnerships
Problem Leakage of CO2e-intensive production to
other states or countries. Solution
Ultimately, a world-wide CO2e emissions
reduction. Intermediate step A region-wide
(Western Climate Initiative) CO2e reduction
strategy. Plan WCI region-wide cap and trade
program http//www.westernclimateinitiative.org/e
webeditpro/items/O104F18808.PDF
130
(No Transcript)
131
Other Regional Initiatives
EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) First regional
CO2e initiative. Operates under auspices of Kyoto
Protocol. Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
(RGGI) First regional CO2e initiative in US.
Began in Sept. 2008. Ten states participate in
RGGI Connecticut, Delaware, Maine, Maryland,
Massachusetts, New Hampshire, New Jersey, New
York, Rhode Island, and Vermont.
132
RGGI
Through laws and/or rules, each state limits
emissions of CO2 from electric power plants,
creates CO2 allowances and establishes the
state's participation in CO2 allowance auctions.
A "Model Rule" drafted jointly by the states
provided a coordinating framework as individual
states developed their laws, rules or
regulations. Regulated power plants will be able
to use a CO2 allowance issued by any of the ten
participating states to demonstrate compliance
with an individual state program. In this manner,
the ten individual state programs, in aggregate,
will function as a single regional compliance
market for CO2 emissions.
133
RGGI
The majority of CO2 allowances issued by each
participating state are distributed through
quarterly auctions. Cap and Auction is a
hybrid of cap and trade and a carbon tax. The
regulatory agency auctions allowances to
regulated emitters. Revenue from auction can be
used to offset adverse impacts on lower-income
people, to subsidize renewable energy or energy
efficiency programs, etc.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)