Title: Portfolio Theory in Illiquid Markets
1Portfolio Theory in Illiquid Markets A New
Formalism
Carlo Acerbi, Abaxbank Giacomo Scandolo,
Università di Firenze
Essex University, Feb 09
2- Introduction
- Assets and Portfolios
- The Value function
- Risk Measures
- Conclusions
3Introduction
Liquidity Risk the blind spot of Portfolio Theory
- Liquidity Risk (LR) is a key feature of
financial markets. Its also the dominant risk of
any big financial crisis which transforms
isolated troubles into systemic epidemics. - Portfolio Theory (PT) has never been
convincingly extended to general illiquid
markets. It does not provide a sufficiently rich
notation to formalize LR-related questions. - Even worse, PT, betrays hidden assumptions of
perfect market liquidity, and therefore doesnt
need be extended, but rewritten from scratch. - Our main goal is to define a formalism for a PT
where basic concepts (Asset, Portfolio, price,
value, risk, ...) are redefined in such a way to
describe illiquid markets. We will work on
general ground with no hypotheses. Hence, ours
will not be a model, but a pure formalism.
4What is Liquidity Risk ?
LR a multi-faceted reality
- Depending on the context, LR, is usually thought
of as - Portfolio LR the risk that a portfolio runs
out of cash money necessary for future payments
(the treasurer point of view) - Market LR the risk of buying or selling on a
market which is shallow compared to the trade
size (the trader point of view) - Systemic LR the risk that the liquidity
circulating in the economy is dried up (the
policy-maker point of view) - LR is all these things together, not only one. An
appropriate formalism should not only describe
one of these aspects, but must lend itself to the
joint formulation of all these problems
5A first fundamental observation
A portfolio is a set, not a sum...
- A Portfolio is essentially a collection of
assets. Yet, we typically do not use a set
notation - but an algebraic notation
- confusing the two concepts of portfolio and
portfolio value and concluding automatically
that the latter is the sum of its consituent
assets values.
- We have seen eq. (1) so many times that it may
appear harmless and even obvious, because its
equation (1) of any financial textbook. On the
contrary we will see that its not only wrong but
even nonsensical in illiquid markets. - (1) is the main taboo to break if we want to
build an appropriate formalism for LR.
6A first fundamental observation (continued)
A portfolio is a set, not a sum...
- Giving up eq. (1) we have
- the value of a portfolio is no more necessarily a
linear function in the portfolio space - Assets and Portfolios are distinct entities. They
do not live in the same vector space (portfolios
are not mere linear combination of assets) - Portfolio p and Portfolio Value V(p) must be
kept distinct conceptually and notationally.
7Second fundamental observation
Alan and Ben
- In a illiquid market it is fundamental to realize
that both the value and the risk of a given
portfolio may take on different values in the
hands of two distinct investors. - Ex let p be a portfolio of very illiquid bonds
with tenor 7-10 ys and face value 1 mln ,
quoting around par - Let Alan be an investor who (for some reason) may
afford to keep p until maturity - Let Ben be an investor who (for some reason) will
be obliged to liquidate periodically large
portions of p. - It is clear that
- For Alan the portfolio is worth more or less 1
mln . For Ben certainly much less because
liquidating he will face a liquidation cost. Ben
may very well be willing to sell it immediately
for much less than 1 mln - Clearly, for Alan the LR of p is zero, whereas
for Ben is very large.
8Second fundamental observation (continued)
An hidden variable ?
- But then there is no value V(p) nor any risk
measure ?(p) depending only on the portfolio,
because otherwise they would have a definite
value and not a different value depending on the
investor. - These functions must therefore depend also on
some further hidden variable X, which PT does
not consider yet. We will have functions of the
kind VX(p) and ?X(p) - The variable X in our formalism will be said
Liquidity Policy (LP) and represents the
constraints (ALM, regulatory, ) to which the
portoflio is subject. - The value of p is higher (the LR of p is lower)
for Alan than for Ben because Alan is subject to
a less restrictive LP than Ben - The correct formalization of LP is the subtlest
ingredient of the formalism.
9- Introduction
- Assets and Portfolios
- The Value function
- Risk Measures
- Conclusions
10Asset
Just a list of market quotes (i.e. an order book)
- An Asset is a good exchanged in the market in
standardized units. At time t the market will
express a number of quotes (both bid and offer)
with relative maximum sizes
- The same information may be condensed in a
function Marginal Supply Demand Curve (MSDC), s
?m(s) defined as the last price m(s) hit in a
trade of size s contracts where conventionally
sgt0 represents a sale and slt0 a purchase of s
contracts.
11Marginal Supply-Demand Curve
An Asset may be identified with its MSDC
- An MSDC contains all the info on the market
prices relative to an Asset at time t. The
prices closest to the origin are the best bid
(mm(0)) and the best offer (m-m(0-)). The
MSDC is decreasing by construction.
12Marginal Supply-Demand Curve (continued)
Asset and MSDC formal definition
- Note that the MSDC is not defined in the origin.
So, we do NOT define any MID-PRICE. Mid prices do
not exist on the market. They are pure
abstractions and we wont need them.
13MSDC and trades
A trades proceeds
- The MSDC is a convenient notation to represent
the proceeds from the sale of s contracts (or the
cost of buying if slt0). In both cases we have eq.
(2).
14MSDC and trades (continued)
A trades proceeds
15The Market
What is the meaning of summing two assets ?
- It is fundamental to realize that the sum A1A2
of two assets A1 and A2 in general is not
defined. In fact, the market does not quotes bids
and asks on any collecion of assets, and
therefore ther is no MSDC in general for a
package containing both contracts A1 and A2. - The dollar () is a very peculiar Asset that we
will denote with A0 whose MSDC is identically
equal to 1 for any value s?? (m(s)1). It
corresponds to cash money and not to generic debt
instruments which instead will be represented by
some nontrivial MSDCs - The Market is a collection ofAssets M A0, A1,
A2, ... ,AN containing always also the dollar.
For what we said above, the market does not
exhibit any structure of linear space, because
the sum of two distinct assets is undefined.
16Criticism to eq. (1)
Simply a nonsensical formula
- We are now in a position to realize that
- does not make any sense at all in an illiquid
market
- The sum of assets is nonsensical between formal
objects because the sum of assets is undefined - The sum cannot be meant among asset values
because assets does not have any value at all.
17Portfolios
Just collections of assets
- The definition of Portfolio is less surprising.
In our notation its the vector of positions in
each markets assets.
- The sum of two portfolios p1p2 is a perfectly
legitimate sum between vectors. The space P of
all portfolios has a natural structure of vector
space. - We denote portfolios in boldface (p, q, ).
Cash-only portfolios a(a, 0,0) will be denoted
as scalars instead. - It remains to understand how to define the
Value of a portfolio. There is no more trivial
answer to this question.
18- Introduction
- Assets and Portfolios
- The Value function
- Risk Measures
- Conclusions
19The Liquidation operator L
Be prepared to liquidate everything
- The proceeds L(p) of a sudden liquidation of a
portfolio p define the operator L
- This may be thought of as an (extremely
conservative !) mark-to-market policy - This MtM policy may be necessary if the
portfolio, for some reason, could be forced to
sudden total liquidations. - This is a first attempt to give a meaning to the
value of p
20The operator U
Dont be prepared to liquidate anything
- If on the contrary we mark long positions to
their best bid and short positions to best
ask, we obtain the following
- This is a widespread mark-to-market policy for
p, but not at all prudential, because it does not
probe at all the market depth. - This MtM policy may be sufficient only when it
is certain (for some reason) that the portfolio
will never face partial liquidations
21Useful definitions
Some useful definitions
- We define liquidation cost the difference CU-L
- We will adopt the following notation
22Some properties of L, U e C
No hypotheses and yet a lot of properties
One can show the following
23Some properties of L, U e C
An example concavity of L(p)
24Some properties of L, U e C
An example concavity of U(p)
25Some properties of L, U e C
An example convexity of C(p)
26The Liquidity Policy (LP)
The set of constraints of a portfolio
- To define a general concept of Mark-to-Market, we
introduce the following
- The idea when we mark a portfolio, we must
consider the constraints we could be forced to
satisfy in the future - These constraints will never breached if we add
cash or reduce all illiquid positions
proportionally
27The Liquidity Policy (LP)
The set of constraints of a portfolio
- The definition of LP is not so abstract as it
may seem. We have examples in everyday finance - ALM constraints
- Risk management limits
- Investment policies
- Margin limits
- Basel II
-
28The Value of a Portfolio
A liquidity sensitive Mark-to-Market
- The key definition of the formalism is
- The value of p is the maximum possible U(q) with
q being attainable from p and compliant with
the LP.
29The Value of a Portfolio
Example cash liquidity policies
- A typical example of LP is the following a bank
estimates a minimum amount of cash to keep for
future payments - The corresponding LP is said a cash liquidity
policy
30The Value of a Portfolio properties
Two consistency checks
- The LP U is the least prudent of all.
31The Value of a Portfolio properties
The fundamental theorem
- The following result can be proved in complete
generality
32Granularity
The other side of the diversification principle
- Concavity of V means
- the value of a blend of portfolios is larger
than the blend of the portfolios values - This is a new kind of diversification principle
- It works on values and not on risks .
- This diversification benefit is related only to
the granularity reduction at current time and has
nothing to do with the correlation of its assets
future dynamics.
33An example of V(p)
34The value of money
The additional value of liquid cash
- Translational supervariance of V, formalizes
that the injection of liquid cash doesnt just
increase nominal value, but also improves the
liquidity and this must reflect in a further
added value that our formalism indeed detects. - This is essentially the old adage a single
added dollar may be worth million dollars (on
the edge of a liquidity crisis) - Notice that all these observations are
qualitatively well known to practitioners. The
novelty is that they find here a correct
quantitative formalization for the first time.
35The optimization problem
A non-trivial but non-serious problem
- The optimization problem hidden in the Value is
nontrivial, but computationally straightforward,
because it can be shown to be a convex problem.
- The problem rarely admits analytical solutions,
but numerically it is always solvable by convex
optimization methods which are generally fast
also for large portfolios - Hadnt we had such a strong result, the
applicability of this formalism for risk
management purposes would have been very
questionable.
36Alan and Ben
37Alan and Ben (follows)
38Alan and Ben (follows)
39Alan and Ben (follows)
40Another example a mutual fund
The NaV of a fund depends on the liquidity of the
assets
- Mutual fund fixed income high rated european
financial floaters. Data from 10/12/2007
41Another example a mutual fund (follows)
42Another example a mutual fund (follows)
concave ! (granularity at work)
43Another example a mutual fund (follows)
44- Introduction
- Assets and Portfolios
- The Value function
- Risk Measures
- Conclusions
45Do we really need liquidity risk measures ?
... or RL is a problem of good accounting ?
- Risk measures are essentially statistics of
future values of a portfolio under chosen
probabilistic assumptions. Our formalism already
incorporates the effect of liquidity in the
value. - Therefore, the use of common risk measures
(stdev, VaR, ...) in this formalism turns out to
be already appropriate for measuring market and
liquidity risk together (and inextricably so) - In our opinion in PT what was really missing was
not some liquidity risk measure, but rather an
appropriate accounting method for general
illiquid markets. - It must be observed that now, modeling the
market dynamics is much more complex, because now
we need to model the joint dynamics of all MSDCs.
The number of degrees of freedom is enormously
higher. - But dont blame the formalism ! This is really
the additional complexity that real markets do
have. There are infinitely more ways to hurt
yourself in a illiquid market than in a ideally
liquid one !
46No hypotheses
We made no hypotheses. These are up to you.
- The formalism does not contain any hypotheses and
is therefore totally general. - To study risks, it is necessary however to
introduce a specific model and therefore to make
probabilistic assumptions on market dynamics. - The hypotheses on the dynamics of MSDCs may be
the most various. These are up to you.
47A toy model
Gaussian market. Exponential MSDCs, cash LP
- Assuming
- we get
- Market Risk is in the dynamics of ai.
- Liquidity Risk is in nonzero ki and in its
randomness - Lets study (ai , ki) joint normal distributed in
different cases
48A toy model
market risk only
market risk and static liquidity risk
market risk and independent random liquidity risk
market risk and correlated random liquidity risk
market risk and correlated random liquidity risk
liq. shocks
49A 10 ys old puzzle
Coherency Axioms are they incompatible with LR ?
Coherent Measures of Risk (Artzner et al. 1997)
have always been criticised for not been
appropriate to account for liquidity
risk In particular Axioms (PH) and (S)
seem manifestly incompatible. The argument goes
- but if I double an illiquid portfolio risk may
become more than double as much ! ...
50Convex Measures of Risk ?
A possible solution changing the axioms
Convex Measures of Risk (Heath, Föllmer et al.,
Frittelli et al., Carr et al.) were introduced to
weaken the axioms replacing (PH) and (S) by a
single weaker axiom
- This approach has the drawback of giving up (PH)
e (S) even in the case of liquid portfolios (e.g.
when they are tiny), when these axioms are
considered correct. - More generally, wed like to recover fully
Coherent Axioms in the limiting case when LR goes
to zero (e.g. portfolios size ltlt market depth).
But within Convex Measures this is not ensured. - Actually, after 10 ys Convex Measures did not
provide any concrete tool for financial risk
management yet.
51Coherency Axioms, revisited
Taking Coherency Axioms seriously
- The argument against the axioms is false,
because X in is ?(X) not a portfolio, but a
portfolio value. The argument tacitly relies on
the assumption that p ?V(p) is a linear function
(our taboo). - Abandoning this argument we do not see any other
reason why we should give up the coherency axioms - Now, VL(p) is no more a linear function and we
may study the behavior of a coherent measure
?L(X) ?(VL(p)) associated to our Value function
- Notice that now the Risk of a portfolio
depends on the chosen LP !
52Coherency Axioms, revisited
Convexity and subvariance of CPRM
- The following result is completely general and
solves the puzzle
- Therefore, convexity of risk measures in the
space of portfolios is a result in our formalism
and not a new axiom ! - Translational subvariance is very clear. The
injection of cash reduces the risk more than its
nominal value, because it improves the portfolio
liquidity.
notice translational invariance had not been
criticized in the theory of convex meaures
53S and PH of CPRMs
For axioms (PH) and (S) results depend on the
liquidity policy
- Example the case of the MtM procedure L
- We see that in this case scaling the portfolio,
risk scales more than proportionally. - Subadditivity wrt portfolios is generally lost,
but it remains valid for discordant portfolios.
For a liquidity policy of type L this is
intuitive.
54S and PH of CPRMs
Axioms (PH) and (S) in the case of cash liquidity
policies
- The result for cash liquidity policies is much
more surprising at first sight
- We notice that as we scale the portfolio, the
risk increases less than proportionally. This may
seem strange, but it is in fact very reasonable
for policies with a fixed b - Subadditivity which in this case is in general no
more true, holds for concordant portfolios.
55S and PH of CPRMs
Axioms (PH) and (S) in the case of cash liquidity
policies... intuition restored
- If we scale also the cash amount of the liquidity
policy we obtain what we expect
- We notice that if we scale the portfolio AND the
liquidity policy, the risk increases more than
proportionally.
56The liquid limit coherency is back
Back to Coherency when markets are liquid
- Every value function VL(p) behaves exactly as
U(p) when there is no LR, namely when - The portfolio size is negligible wrt the market
depth - The assets MSDCs are flat
- Investors have no liquidity constraints
- Therefore, U may be thought of as a tool to
probe the liquid limit of the formalism. It is
important to see that CPRMs with U satisfy
formally all coherency axioms
57- Introduction
- Assets and Portfolios
- The Value function
- Risk Measures
- Conclusions
58Conclusions
- We have described a general formalism for
portfolio theory in illiquid markets, based on
the observation that Assets and Portfolios are
concepts to be kept distinct, which do not live
in the same vector space and for which distinct
categories apply. Assets have prices but not
values and Portfolios have values but not prices.
- We recover the standard portfolio theory
formalism in the limit of liquid markets. - The formalism is completely free from
hypotheses. Hypotheses are needed for any
implementation, in particular, for the stochastic
modeling of MSDCs. - The Value function of a Portfolio turns out to
depend from a new concept of liquidity policy,
which relates the evaluation of the portfolio to
the liquidity needs it has to sustain with its
cashflows. This is shown to be always a concave
map on the space of portfolios. We interpret this
as a granularity effect, which is the liquidity
side of the diversification principle.
59Conclusions
- The Value function hides a high dimensional
optimization problem. This could generally
represent a serious obstacle for implementation
in general cases. Fortunately this is not the
case, because the problem can be shown to be
convex in general. - Analytically tractable cases are described, but
in general this formalism requires numerical
convex optimization methods. - This formalism can be adopted with any portfolio
risk measure. However, when used with Coherent
Measures of Risk, this formalism solves a
longstanding puzzle. CMR were criticized for not
being compatible with liquidity risk. In this
formalism one sees that the criticism was not
correct. The axioms of coherence need no change
for encompassing liquidity risk. It was necessary
to devise a new accounting method and not a new
class of risk measures. - The formalism naturally defines Coherent
Portfolio Risk Measures which are induced on the
space of portfolios by the choice of a CMR and a
liquidity policy. CPRMs turn out to be convex and
translational supervariant. The properties of
subadditivity and positive homogeneity do not
hold anymore on CPRMs and their deformed version
is shown to depend on the chosen liquidity
policy.
60References
- C. Acerbi e G. Scandolo, Liquidity Risk and
Coherent Measures of Risk, to appear on
Quantitative Finance, 2008. - C. Acerbi, in Pillar II in the New Basel
Accord, RISK books, ed. A. Resti, 2008