Title: Market power, collusion, and oligopoly
1Market power, collusion, and oligopoly
- Market power ability to influence market prices
- Acquiring market power mergers
- Horizontal mergers regulated by the DOJ/FTC
guidelines (an interesting read!) based on loss
of welfare due to the merger
- Welfare trade-off in a merger on the upside,
mergers can decrease cost and also increase the
range of products available. On the downside
bigger firms have more market power, quantity
produced is likely to decrease, resulting in
higher prices and a welfare loss - Overall, welfare effects of a merger are
ambiguous a merger may increase or decrease
welfare
2Antitrust (I)
- Sherman Act (1890) and Clayton Act (1914) give
courts power to prevent mergers that reduce
competition
- A double monopoly two firms A and B, both
monopolists in their product market. If A uses
Bs output as an input, the outcome (evaluated in
terms of welfare) is clearly worse than in the
situation where As input were purchased in a
competitive market - 60k question whats worse than a monopoly?
- Answer a chain of monopolies.
3Vertical mergers
- If the chain of monopolies becomes a single
monopoly through vertical integration, consumers
benefit
- But in general the welfare effects of a vertical
merger are ambiguous mergers between competitive
firms and monopolies may decrease welfare
4Predatory pricing
- Acquiring market power revisited predatory
pricing
- Decreasing price to drive out competition
- Price wars Intel and AMD
- The predator has to produce output it may incur
losses if sells at a low price. The firm thats
preyed upon may shut down during the price war
- Perhaps gaining reputation (warning to future
entrants) is the best purpose of predatory
pricing
- Predatory pricing (rather, some forms of price
discrimination that tend to create a monopoly,
lessen competition or injure competitors)
illegal under the Robinson-Patman (1938) act
5A bit of game theory
- Collusion firms set prices and quantities. Two
forms really by direct contact and tacit
collusion
- What price and quantity is most likely to occur
from collusion?
- Monopoly profits highest possible profits
achieved
- Smoking gun Christies and Sothebys posted on
their website that talks between their
representatives enabled them to set the
commissions
6Prisoners dilemma
- Want to play a game? Go to Mike Shors website
at Owen
- Two suspects (A and B) committed a crime and were
arrested
- Interrogated separately they may confess (C) or
deny (D)
- Payoffs more is preferred to less!
7Prisoners dilemma
Crook B
D
C
C
2,2
10,-1
Crook A
-1,10
6,6
D
As payoff is the first number in each cell the
second is Bs payoff
8Solving the PD
- Best outcome (D,D) Pareto Optimal
- But theres always an incentive for a player to
deviate from (D,D)
- In fact, choosing C always gets you a better
payoff than choosing D Check this!
- Nash Equilibrium a pair of strategies (SA, SB)
if A sticks to his NE strategy SA, B has no
profitable deviation and similar for B.
- Alternatively No unilateral profitable
deviations from the Nash equilibrium exist!
9Games
- Find the NE of the following 2-player game
Player B
D
C
C
2,3
-1,5
Player A
3,-1
-2,-2
D
Check for profitable deviations Player A first,
then player B.
Are any strategies dominated?
10Repeated PD
- If play for a finite number of times the same PD
game, start with the last period. What would you
do if you were Mr. A?
- Go to the next-to-last period. What would you do
if you were Mr. A?
- Collusion? There is no collusion in the
finite-period repeated PD?
- What if the game is repeated an infinite (or
random) number of times?
- If players put enough weight on future streams of
income, collusion may be enforced.
11The infinitely repeated PD
- Refer to the payoffs in the table on p. 7 both
players would be better off if they played in
each period (D,D). They choose to play C because
of the incentive that the opponents have to
cheat by playing C. - Mr. A offers the following plan to Mr. B he
will start by playing D in the first round will
continue to play D as long as Mr. B plays D if a
deviation is detected, Mr. A will play C forever.
This is a grim trigger strategy (deviation from
D triggers punishment of the opponent forever).
12Infinitely repeated PD (contd)
- To analyze the conditions under which the trigger
strategy is an equilibrium, we have to see if
there are any unilateral profitable deviations.
- A bit of notation is required since the game is
played in discrete time periods t1,2,3, let the
value of 1 in period t1 be equal to d in
period t (d is usually referred to as the
discount factor and incorporates the effect of
a non-zero interest rate d1/(1r) where r is
the inter-period interest rate thus, d must be
less than 1). - d may be interpreted as the present value of 1
that is obtained one period in the future.
- Intuitively to have 100 in your bank account
one year from now, you have to put less than 100
in your bank account today the amount is exactly
100/(1r)100 d
13Trigger strategies
- If Mr. B plays D forever, his payoff is
- 66 d 6d26 d3
- If he defects/cheats by playing C, his payoff is
102 d2 d22 d3
- Helpful aa da d2 ad3a/(1- d) for any
number a and for any d that is less than 1 and
greater than zero
- Compare the two payoffs above if
- 6/(1- d)102 d/(1- d)
- Thus, for the trigger strategy to be an
equilibrium, we need d1/2.
- Intuition if the discount factor is large enough
(i.e., if you care enough about future payoffs),
the collusive outcome (D,D) may be enforced in
all periods.
14Mixed strategies
- If you play paper-rock-scissors, announcing a
strategy to your opponent (e.g., you will play S)
and sticking to it guarantees that your payoff
will be equal to zero (your opponent will choose
R and will win). - The only way to win in this game is to randomize
over strategies choose P, R and S with some
probability.
- Another example Matching pennies
15Games
- Find the (pure strategy) NE of the following
2-player game
Different
Tail
Head
Head
-1,1
1,-1
Same
-1,1
1,-1
Tail
Are any strategies dominated? No. In addition,
no NE in pure strategies exist!
16Matching pennies
- The only way to (sometimes) win in this game (as
in P-R-S) is to randomize over your choice of H
and T.
- To find the equilibrium probabilities of playing
H and T, observe that if a strategy (i.e.,
playing H or T) is used in equilibrium, it must
yield the same (expected) payoff as all the other
strategies that are used in equilibrium. If a
strategy has a higher expected payoff than all
the others, you will only use that strategy! - So suppose that the same player chooses H with
probability p, and T with probability 1-p
- Similarly, the different player chooses H with
probability r, and T with probability 1-r.
- Lets find p and r so that the expected payoff
for the two players of playing H and T are the
same.
17Mixed strategies
- Mr. same if he plays H, his expected payoff
is 1r -1(1-r) (he gets 1 if his opponent plays H
this happens with probability r, and -1 if his
opponent plays T, which happens with probability
1-r. - If Mr. same plays T, he gets -1r(1-r).
- By definition of a mixed strategy equilibrium,
the expected payoffs from playing H and T should
be the same, so we need 2r-11-2r, from which it
follows that r.5. - Same argument holds for Mr. different, thus, p
must be equal to .5.
18Matching pennies
- Interpretation to maximize expected payoff, each
player in the game of matching pennies chooses to
play T or H each with probability ½. If a higher
probability is put on one of the strategies,
expected payoff is strictly less (can you show
this?). - This game is known as a zero-sum game the sum
of payoffs in each of the four possible outcomes
is equal to zero.
- What is the equilibrium expected payoff for the
two players?
- What are the corresponding probabilities and
expected payoffs in the P-R-S game?
19Oligopoly
- Price and quantity competition respective
games are Bertrand and Cournot
- Cournot quantity competition. Two (or more)
firms that share the market for a homogeneous
good
- Inverse demand P(X) a b X gives market price
when the quantity produced by the two
oligopolists is equal to X.
- For simplicity both firms have constant marginal
cost equal to c.
20Exercise 8.1
- If market demand is D(P)50-2P, what is inverse
demand?
- Write X 50-2P and solve for P. In this case
P25-X/2.
- So P(X)25-X/2 is inverse market demand
21Cournot (quantity competition)
- First firm chooses x1 to maximize its profit
(P(x1x2)-c) x1 (revenue minus cost)
- Note that the optimal x1 will be a function of
x2. This is the first firms reaction function
x1R1(x2).
- Similarly, for firm 2, x2R2(x1)
- Graphically
22x2
R1(x2)
X2
R2(x1)
x1
X1
23Finding reaction functionsExercise 8.2
- P(X)5-X
- Marginal cost c1
- ?1 (5-(x1x2)-1)x1
- ?2 (5-(x1x2)-1)x2
- Differentiate ??1/?x14-2x1-x20
- ??1/?x14-2x2-x10
- First x1(4-x2)/2R1(x2) (1)
- Second x2(4-x1)/2R2(x1) (2)
- Solve for x1 and x2 take x2 from (2) and plug it
into (1) get x1(4-(4-x1)/2)/2, so
- 2x1 2-x1/2 or 3x1/22 x14/3
- x2 will be equal to x1 (check this!)
24What if
- P(X) a b X
- Marginal cost c
- Can you find the reaction functions?
- Can you find the Cournot quantities?
- Suppose there are three firms in a market
- Can you find the reaction functions?
- Can you find the Cournot quantities?
25Bertrand model (price competition)
- Two firms, same marginal cost c, homogeneous
product
- Puzzling result price charged by the two firms
equals marginal cost
- Why?
- Suppose that a firm charges a higher price than
the other. What is that firms profit?
- So both firms must charge the same price
- If price is above marginal cost
- Undercutting the rivals cost by a penny gets you
all the market (a simplification, certainly)
- If price is below marginal cost
- Firms incur losses
- Is (c,c) a Nash Equilibrium?
26Bertrand
- Yes there is no profitable deviation
- The profits of the two firms are 0
- Compare this with the profit with Cournot
(quantity) competition
27Collusion in the Bertrand (price competition)
model
- Both firms would be best off if they choose the
monopoly price.
- Fear of being cheated (e.g., the opponent charges
the monopoly price minus a penny) makes
competitors choose a price that is equal to
marginal cost. - What if the price competition game is repeated an
infinite number of times? Analysis of the
infinitely repeated PD game suggests that if the
discount rate is high enough, collusion may be
enforced with infinite repetition.
28Monopolistic competition
- Product differentiation products that differ
across firms in their characteristics
- Pepsi and Coca-Cola?
- Demand more elastic than the one faced by a
monopolist because elasticity of demand depends
on the availability of substitutes
- Firms maximize profit MRMC
- In the short run a monopolistically competitive
firm may earn positive profit, but long-run entry
drives profits to zero
29Monopolistic competition
Long Run
Short Run
MC
MC
AC
PSR
AC
Short run profit
SR demand
PLRAC Zero profit
MR
PLR
LR demand
LRMR
QLR
Quantity
QSR
Quantity