Title: NAMA
1NAMA
21. The negotiations are to be conducted within a
framework that does not represent the position of
developing countries
- The framework is provided by the Debez Text
- Derbez formula was largely based on the
Canada-EU-US proposal of August 2003. - The Derbez text was presented to the WTOs Cancún
Ministerial Conference on 13 September 2003, and
was subsequently rejected - The Derbez annex when presented to the Members in
July , 2004 was strongly criticised for having
excluded developing country concerns from the
text, - After considerable debate, developing countries
agreed to the inclusion of Annex B within the
July package with Paragraph 1 of the annex. This
states that the key elements within the annex are
still not agreed and thus remain to be
negotiated. - In developed countries it was hailed as a big
victory for business. - Contrary to the spirit of the Development Round.
3Key Elements
- the formula for tariff reduction,
- treatment of unbound tariffs,
- flexibilities for developing countries,
-
- the sectoral component and,
- preference erosion issues
4The central principle
- The central principle as mandated by paragraph 16
of the Doha Ministerial Declaration reads - The negotiations shall take fully into account
the special needs and interests of developing and
least-developed country participants, including
through less than full reciprocity in reduction
commitments, - What is implication of the July framework in
practice?
52. Negotiations on tariff reduction More than
reciprocity
- a non-linear formula on a line-by-line basis
- Non linearity means Greater cut in higher
tariffs and Harmonisation which means more than
reciprocity for developing countries. - The ultimate reduction will be based on the
coefficient but in all scenarios drastic cuts for
the developing countries with no flexibilities. - Swiss formula T1 (BT0)/(BT0) if B T0
Then cut is 50, if Bgt T0 then cut is less than
50 and vice versa.\
6The proposals implications
- Single B for both developed and developing
countries - Different coefficients for B for developed and
developing countries. Higher B for developing
countries. Higher the coefficient B, smaller the
cut. US also proposes it but with no
flexibilities for developing countries. - ABI proposal Weight B by average tariff rates
- T1 (BT0Ta)/(B Ta T0)
- In any case, due to the lower initial rates,
developed countries will not be affected much.
But drastic change in developing country rates - Mehta even by ABI formula base rate of 33.2
will come down to 15.8 - Countries will experience particularly drastic
reductions in those lines which they have tried
to protect through tariffs which are higher than
the average
7Line by line basis No policy space for
protecting the sensitive items
- Developing countries need policy space which will
be badly hurt by line-by-line tariff cuts. - Pattern in Optimal tariff structure there is a
pattern of optimal tariffs in different sectors
(at different phases of a countrys industrial
development. - It should be applied on average tariff rates as
it happened in the Uruguay round on agriculture
tariff reduction. These countries need to demand
such flexibility for developing countries. - Tariff reductions should not be allowed on line
by line basis
8Tariff cuts and SDT
- Flexibilities to developing countries in the
framework - longer time frame,
- Less than formula cut by 10-15
- 5 concession in tariff line bindings
- These proposals also opposed if less than
reciprocity is offered
9Is is justified in the development round
- In the Uruguay Round, US opposition to the use of
a single non-linear formula ensured that
countries were able to determine their own
approach to tariff reduction. - Developing countries adopted a request-offer
approach to the negotiations allowing proper
flexibility in the liberalisation undertaken. - Doha round is billed as development round yet
such flexibilities are denied to developing
countries.
103. Treatment of unbound rates double concession
by developing countries
- Provision countries which have left particular
tariff lines unbound will be required to
implement tariff reductions on those lines via
the same formula as bound tariffs, - Base rate Twice the MFN applied rate as at 14
November 2001. - The implication developing countries should
both bind and apply the tariff reduction formula
to unbound tariff lines. - Furthermore, since there is a large difference
between bound and applied rates in developing
countries, it is criticised strongly. - Developing countries are advocating that bound
and unbound tariffs should be treated
differently. - developing countries should not make a double
concession of both binding and cutting tariffs
via the formula in the same round
11Proposals focus on base rates
- ABI Multiply base rate by a number ( to be
negotiated and bind them at an average - Canada, HK, Newzealand, China, Norway Add 5 to
the base rate - Pakistan add 30 to the base rate
- Mexico Non linear mark up
- Malaysia Average of 25 with ceiling of 40
- Most proposals on the base rates and seek to
correct the gap between bound and applied rates
but the basic issue of substantial concession
remains.
124. Binding of tariff lines Substantial
concession by developing countries
- Unwritten assumption countries should bind 100
tariff lines. - Flexibility to developing countries they will
be required to raise their binding coverage to a
minimum of 95 of non-agricultural tariff lines.
Thus the concession is that 5 tariff lines may
be unbound. - Implication for developing countries
substantial concession by many countries which
have substantial unbound rates. - LDCs exempt both from applying the tariff
reduction formula and from participation in the
sectoral initiative (Para 9). Yet, as part of
their contribution to this round of negotiations,
they are expected to substantially increase their
level of binding commitments. - developing countries with less than 35 of
non-agricultural tariff lines bound would be
exempt from the tariff reduction formula. But
they are expected to bind 100 tariff lines at
an average level not higher than the average of
all developing countries bound tariffs. They
would also be required to participate in the
sectoral initiative. This implies tariff
reduction and bindings. Criteria of 35 should be
discussed and overrun.
13Sectoral approach
- Paragraph 7 of Annex B as it stands at present
would require all WTO members except LDCs to
enter into negotiations aiming at the elimination
or harmonisation of non-agricultural tariffs in
sectors to be decided during the process of
negotiations. - Mandatory participation by all countries was a
central requirement of the joint Canada-EU-US
paper submitted to the WTO in August 2003, and
hence it is retained in the current draft. - developing countries have consistently maintained
that they should participate in any sectoral NAMA
negotiations on a voluntary basis only. They
should not give any concession here
14Erosion of generalised preference
- Margins of preferential access which LDCs exports
currently enjoy will be eroded. - Sectoral initiatives would include sectors of
export interest of developing countries. Such
drastic liberalisation would effectively wipe out
existing preferences enjoyed by them in their
most important export sectors. -
- paragraph 16 of Annex B does no more than
instruct the NAMA negotiating group to take into
consideration the needs of those WTO members
which stand to lose as a result of preference
erosion under the Doha Round. - The IMF has intervened in the context of
preference erosion through its Trade Integration
Mechanism (TIM), introduced in April 2004. The
TIM is designed to pave the way for more
ambitious trade liberalisation at the WTO by
providing finance to meet balance of payments
shortfalls arising from preference erosion or
other losses caused by global trade
liberalisation. - The IMF has made clear that it is not offering
new financing through the TIM but rather a
repackaging of loans already available through
existing IMF lending instruments. - This would increase their debt burden.
- the African Group proposed a correction
coefficient in order to maintain or improve the
margins for products which currently enjoy
preferential access but which are threatened by
NAMA negotiations at the WTO.
15NTBs
- paragraph 14 of Annex B undertakes to examine
NTBs in the context of the NAMA negotiations. - No substantial progress.
- More than 2000 NTBs identified.
- Substantial proportion of trade under NTBs in
developed countries . For India estimates have
been made over 44 of trade with Us is subject
to such NTBs - Tendency to refer them to other committees within
the WTO to discuss, with the NAMA negotiating
group overseeing progress. - A number of developing countries expressed
concern at the move. It could remove some NTBs
from the compass of the NAMA negotiating group
altogether.
16Are NAMA negotiations really directed to benefit
developing countries
- The NAMA negotiations threaten to open up
developing countries markets not for their own
benefit but for the benefit of export interests
of other economies. - It has been stated explicitly by developed
countries negotiators such as the EUs Trade
Commissioner Peter Mandelson that developing
countries must be made to pay for the possible
future abolition of rich country agricultural
subsidies (even as these are being ruled illegal
by the WTO) by opening up their own industrial
and services sectors to multinational
corporations based in the North.
17Will tariff reduction promote growth
- Yilmaz Akyuz Developed countries during their
development phase had tariffs that were far
higher than the current tariffs in developing
countries. For example, the United States had
average applied tariffs of 40-50 for much of
the century 1820-1920. Even in 1950, its average
tariff was 14. In comparison, the average rate
in 2001 in developing countries as a whole was
8.1. - An UNCTAD study on 50 developing countries showed
that only 20 that liberalised their imports had
managed to expand their manufacturing exports to
any significant extent, and of these only 10
expanded their manufacturing value-added as
well. Half of the countries surveyed experienced
deindustrialisation. There was little evidence
they could upgrade their industries.
18Some examples
-
- cote dIvoire witnessed the virtual collapse of
its chemicals, textiles, shoe and automobile
assembly sectors when tariffs were cut by 40 in
1986. - Following its major trade liberalisation
programme in 1993, Kenyas beverages, tobacco,
textiles, sugar, leather, cement and glass
products sectors have all struggled to survive
import competition. - Structural adjustment in the 1990s also led to
the closure of large numbers of manufacturing
firms in Cameroon, Malawi, Mozambique, Tanzania,
Zambia and Zimbabwe, to name a few. - Hungary closure of thousands of SMEs
- While more powerful developing country economies
may be able to benefit from the new
opportunities, the majority will be excluded from
the welfare gains.
19Employment
- World Banks survey of studies into the
relationship between globalisation and
unemployment rate concluded During periods of
trade liberalization, and more generally of
economic reform, job destruction rates can be
expected to proceed at a much faster pace than
job creation. Globalization could therefore be
associated with higher unemployment rates. - Several developing countries including Latin
America have experienced dramatic rise in
unemployment/underemployment
20Fiscal stability
Loss of revenue may be substantial for these
countries two options raise other taxes, cut
down of expenditures affect expenditures on
education, health care and such asset building
programmes.
21Trade off between present and future
- Developing countries may be sacrificing their
future for a bit of market access for the
present. Even if developing countries get access
to developed countries markets, that may be of
benefit to products they presently make, but it
hurt their future prospects of promoting to high
value added products that they can potentially
make (as the developing countries tariffs on
these would have been lowered). - UNCTAD senior economist, Mehdi Shaffaeddin,
warned developing countries against hoping to get
some benefit for their labour-intensive
industry, and in return giving up their
possibility for high value-added industry. This
would be the end of their industrialisation. - Developing countries need strive hard to obtain
flexibilities to address their developmental
sensitivities.