Title: Decision Analysis
1Chapter 12 Decision Analysis
2Chapter Topics
- Components of Decision Making
- Decision Making without Probabilities
- Decision Making with Probabilities
- Decision Analysis with Additional Information
- Utility
3Decision Analysis Components of Decision Making
- A state of nature is an actual event that may
occur in the future. - A payoff table is a means of organizing a
decision situation, presenting the payoffs from
different decisions given the various states of
nature.
Table 12.1 Payoff Table
4Decision AnalysisDecision Making Without
Probabilities
Figure 12.1
5Decision Analysis Decision Making without
Probabilities
- Decision situation
- Decision-Making Criteria maximax, maximin,
minimax, minimax regret, Hurwicz, and equal
likelihood
Table 12.2 Payoff Table for the Real Estate
Investments
6Decision Making without Probabilities Maximax
Criterion
- In the maximax criterion the decision maker
selects the decision that will result in the
maximum of maximum payoffs an optimistic
criterion.
Table 12.3 Payoff Table Illustrating a Maximax
Decision
7Decision Making without Probabilities Maximin
Criterion
- In the maximin criterion the decision maker
selects the decision that will reflect the
maximum of the minimum payoffs a pessimistic
criterion.
Table 12.4 Payoff Table Illustrating a Maximin
Decision
8Decision Making without Probabilities Minimax
Regret Criterion
- Regret is the difference between the payoff from
the best decision and all other decision payoffs. - The decision maker attempts to avoid regret by
selecting the decision alternative that minimizes
the maximum regret.
Table 12.6 Regret Table Illustrating the
Minimax Regret Decision
9Decision Making without Probabilities Hurwicz
Criterion
- The Hurwicz criterion is a compromise between the
maximax and maximin criterion. - A coefficient of optimism, ?, is a measure of the
decision makers optimism. - The Hurwicz criterion multiplies the best payoff
by ? and the worst payoff by 1- ?., for each
decision, and the best result is selected. - Decision
Values - Apartment building 50,000(.4)
30,000(.6) 38,000 - Office building 100,000(.4) -
40,000(.6) 16,000 - Warehouse 30,000(.4)
10,000(.6) 18,000
10Decision Making without Probabilities Equal
Likelihood Criterion
- The equal likelihood ( or Laplace) criterion
multiplies the decision payoff for each state of
nature by an equal weight, thus assuming that the
states of nature are equally likely to occur. - Decision
Values - Apartment building 50,000(.5)
30,000(.5) 40,000 - Office building 100,000(.5) -
40,000(.5) 30,000 - Warehouse 30,000(.5)
10,000(.5) 20,000
11Decision Making without Probabilities Summary of
Criteria Results
- A dominant decision is one that has a better
payoff than another decision under each state of
nature. - The appropriate criterion is dependent on the
risk personality and philosophy of the decision
maker. - Criterion
Decision (Purchase) - Maximax Office building
- Maximin Apartment building
- Minimax regret Apartment building
- Hurwicz Apartment building
- Equal likelihood Apartment building
12Decision Making without Probabilities Solution
with QM for Windows (1 of 3)
Exhibit 12.1
13Decision Making without Probabilities Solution
with QM for Windows (2 of 3)
Exhibit 12.2
14Decision Making without Probabilities Solution
with QM for Windows (3 of 3)
Exhibit 12.3
15Decision Making without Probabilities Solution
with Excel
Exhibit 12.4
16Decision Making with Probabilities Expected Value
- Expected value is computed by multiplying each
decision outcome under each state of nature by
the probability of its occurrence. -
-
- EV(Apartment) 50,000(.6) 30,000(.4)
42,000 - EV(Office) 100,000(.6) - 40,000(.4) 44,000
- EV(Warehouse) 30,000(.6) 10,000(.4)
22,000
Table 12.7 Payoff table with Probabilities for
States of Nature
17Decision Making with Probabilities Expected
Opportunity Loss
- The expected opportunity loss is the expected
value of the regret for each decision. - The expected value and expected opportunity loss
criterion result in the same decision. -
-
- EOL(Apartment) 50,000(.6) 0(.4) 30,000
- EOL(Office) 0(.6) 70,000(.4) 28,000
- EOL(Warehouse) 70,000(.6) 20,000(.4)
50,000
Table 12.8 Regret (Opportunity Loss) Table
with Probabilities for States of Nature
18Expected Value Problems Solution with QM for
Windows
Exhibit 12.5
19Expected Value Problems Solution with Excel and
Excel QM (1 of 2)
Exhibit 12.6
20Expected Value Problems Solution with Excel and
Excel QM (2 of 2)
Exhibit 12.7
21Decision Making with Probabilities Expected Value
of Perfect Information
- The expected value of perfect information (EVPI)
is the maximum amount a decision maker would pay
for additional information. - EVPI equals the expected value given perfect
information minus the expected value without
perfect information. - EVPI equals the expected opportunity loss (EOL)
for the best decision.
22Decision Making with Probabilities EVPI Example
(1 of 2)
Table 12.9 Payoff Table with Decisions, Given
Perfect Information
23Decision Making with Probabilities EVPI Example
(2 of 2)
- Decision with perfect information
- 100,000(.60) 30,000(.40) 72,000
- Decision without perfect information
- EV(office) 100,000(.60) - 40,000(.40)
44,000 -
- EVPI 72,000 - 44,000 28,000
- EOL(office) 0(.60) 70,000(.4) 28,000
24Decision Making with Probabilities EVPI with QM
for Windows
Exhibit 12.8
25Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
(1 of 4)
- A decision tree is a diagram consisting of
decision nodes (represented as squares),
probability nodes (circles), and decision
alternatives (branches).
Table 12.10 Payoff Table for Real Estate
Investment Example
26Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
(2 of 4)
Figure 12.1 Decision Tree for Real Estate
Investment Example
27Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
(3 of 4)
- The expected value is computed at each
probability node - EV(node 2) .60(50,000) .40(30,000)
42,000 - EV(node 3) .60(100,000) .40(-40,000)
44,000 - EV(node 4) .60(30,000) .40(10,000)
22,000 - Branches with the greatest expected value are
selected.
28Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
(4 of 4)
Figure 12.2 Decision Tree with Expected Value at
Probability Nodes
29Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
with QM for Windows
Exhibit 12.9
30Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
with Excel and TreePlan (1 of 4)
Exhibit 12.10
31Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
with Excel and TreePlan (2 of 4)
Exhibit 12.11
32Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
with Excel and TreePlan (3 of 4)
Exhibit 12.12
33Decision Making with Probabilities Decision Trees
with Excel and TreePlan (4 of 4)
Exhibit 12.13
34Decision Making with Probabilities Sequential
Decision Trees (1 of 4)
- A sequential decision tree is used to illustrate
a situation requiring a series of decisions. - Used where a payoff table, limited to a single
decision, cannot be used. - Real estate investment example modified to
encompass a ten-year period in which several
decisions must be made -
35Decision Making with Probabilities Sequential
Decision Trees (2 of 4)
Figure 12.3 Sequential Decision Tree
36Decision Making with Probabilities Sequential
Decision Trees (3 of 4)
- Decision is to purchase land highest net
expected value (1,160,000). - Payoff of the decision is 1,160,000.
-
37Decision Making with Probabilities Sequential
Decision Trees (4 of 4)
Figure 12.4 Sequential Decision Tree with Nodal
Expected Values
38Sequential Decision Tree Analysis Solution with
QM for Windows
Exhibit 12.14
39Sequential Decision Tree Analysis Solution with
Excel and TreePlan
Exhibit 12.15
40Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Bayesian Analysis (1 of 3)
- Bayesian analysis uses additional information to
alter the marginal probability of the occurrence
of an event. - In real estate investment example, using expected
value criterion, best decision was to purchase
office building with expected value of 44,000,
and EVPI of 28,000. -
Table 12.11 Payoff Table for the Real Estate
Investment Example
41Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Bayesian Analysis (2 of 3)
- A conditional probability is the probability that
an event will occur given that another event has
already occurred. - Economic analyst provides additional information
for real estate investment decision, forming
conditional probabilities - g good economic conditions
- p poor economic conditions
- P positive economic report
- N negative economic report
- P(P?g) .80 P(N?g) .20
- P(P?p) .10 P(N?p) .90
-
42Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Bayesian Analysis (3 of 3)
- A posterior probability is the altered marginal
probability of an event based on additional
information. - Prior probabilities for good or poor economic
conditions in real estate decision - P(g) .60 P(p) .40
- Posterior probabilities by Bayes rule
- P(g?P) P(P?g)P(g)/P(P?g)P(g) P(P?p)P(p)
- (.80)(.60)/(.80)(.60)
(.10)(.40) .923 - Posterior (revised) probabilities for decision
- P(g?N) .250 P(p?P) .077 P(p?N) .750
43Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Decision Trees with Posterior
Probabilities (1 of 4)
- Decision tree with posterior probabilities differ
from earlier versions in that - Two new branches at beginning of tree represent
report outcomes. - Probabilities of each state of nature are
posterior probabilities from Bayes rule.
44Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Decision Trees with Posterior
Probabilities (2 of 4)
Figure 12.5 Decision Tree with Posterior
Probabilities
45Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Decision Trees with Posterior
Probabilities (3 of 4)
- EV (apartment building) 50,000(.923)
30,000(.077) - 48,460
- EV (strategy) 89,220(.52) 35,000(.48)
63,194
46Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Decision Trees with Posterior
Probabilities (4 of 4)
Figure 12.6 Decision Tree Analysis
47Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Computing Posterior Probabilities
with Tables
Table 12.12 Computation of Posterior
Probabilities
48Decision Analysis with Additional Information
Computing Posterior Probabilities with Excel
Exhibit 12.16
49Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Expected Value of Sample Information
- The expected value of sample information (EVSI)
is the difference between the expected value with
and without information - For example problem, EVSI 63,194 - 44,000
19,194 - The efficiency of sample information is the ratio
of the expected value of sample information to
the expected value of perfect information - efficiency EVSI /EVPI 19,194/ 28,000 .68
50Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Utility (1 of 2)
Table 12.13 Payoff Table for Auto Insurance
Example
51Decision Analysis with Additional
Information Utility (2 of 2)
- Expected Cost (insurance) .992(500)
.008(500) 500 - Expected Cost (no insurance) .992(0)
.008(10,000) 80 - Decision should be do not purchase insurance, but
people almost always do purchase insurance. - Utility is a measure of personal satisfaction
derived from money. - Utiles are units of subjective measures of
utility. - Risk averters forgo a high expected value to
avoid a low-probability disaster. - Risk takers take a chance for a bonanza on a very
low-probability event in lieu of a sure thing.
52Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (1 of
9)
53Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (2 of
9)
- Determine the best decision without
probabilities using the 5 criteria of the
chapter. - Determine best decision with probabilities
assuming .70 probability of good conditions, .30
of poor conditions. Use expected value and
expected opportunity loss criteria. - Compute expected value of perfect information.
- Develop a decision tree with expected value at
the nodes. - Given following, P(P?g) .70, P(N?g) .30,
P(P?p) .20, P(N?p) .80, determine posterior
probabilities using Bayes rule. - Perform a decision tree analysis using the
posterior probability obtained in part e.
54Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (3 of
9)
Step 1 (part a) Determine decisions without
probabilities. Maximax Decision Maintain status
quo Decisions Maximum Payoffs Expand
800,000 Status quo 1,300,000 (maximum) Sell
320,000 Maximin Decision Expand Decisions Mini
mum Payoffs Expand 500,000 (maximum) Status
quo -150,000 Sell 320,000
55Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (4 of
9)
Minimax Regret Decision Expand Decisions Maximu
m Regrets Expand 500,000 (minimum) Status
quo 650,000 Sell 980,000 Hurwicz (? .3)
Decision Expand Expand 800,000(.3)
500,000(.7) 590,000 Status quo 1,300,000(.3)
- 150,000(.7) 285,000 Sell 320,000(.3)
320,000(.7) 320,000
56Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (5 of
9)
Equal Likelihood Decision Expand Expand
800,000(.5) 500,000(.5) 650,000 Status
quo 1,300,000(.5) - 150,000(.5)
575,000 Sell 320,000(.5) 320,000(.5)
320,000 Step 2 (part b) Determine Decisions
with EV and EOL. Expected value decision
Maintain status quo Expand 800,000(.7)
500,000(.3) 710,000 Status quo
1,300,000(.7) - 150,000(.3) 865,000 Sell
320,000(.7) 320,000(.3) 320,000
57Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (6 of
9)
Expected opportunity loss decision Maintain
status quo Expand 500,000(.7) 0(.3)
350,000 Status quo 0(.7)
650,000(.3) 195,000 Sell
980,000(.7) 180,000(.3) 740,000 Step 3
(part c) Compute EVPI. EV given perfect
information 1,300,000(.7) 500,000(.3)
1,060,000 EV without perfect information
1,300,000(.7) - 150,000(.3) 865,000 EVPI
1.060,000 - 865,000 195,000
58Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (7 of
9)
Step 4 (part d) Develop a decision tree.
59Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (8 of
9)
Step 5 (part e) Determine posterior
probabilities. P(g?P) P(P?g)P(g)/P(P?g)P(g)
P(P?p)P(p) (.70)(.70)/(.70)(.70)
(.20)(.30) .891
P(p?P) .109 P(g?N) P(N?g)P(g)/P(N?g)P(
g) P(N?p)P(p) (.30)(.70)/(.30)(.70)
(.80)(.30) .467 P(p?N) .533
60Decision Analysis Example Problem Solution (9 of
9)
Step 6 (part f) Decision tree analysis.
61Assignment for Chapter 12 Problems 5,
10,17,19,28, and 35