Title: Urban Water Conservation: Comparing Price and Non-price Policies
1Urban Water Conservation Comparing Price and
Non-price Policies
- Sheila M. Olmstead
- Yale University
- Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
- June 17, 2009
2(No Transcript)
3Drought-Stricken South Facing Tough Choices
October 16, 2007
State eases water rules, but urges
restraint Atlanta Journal-Constitution June 10,
2009
4Water Demand and Prices
- On average, a 10 increase in the price of water
reduces residential demand by 3 to 4 in U.S.
cities. - This is similar to the price sensitivity of
residential electricity demand. - The response of water demand to price increases
is stronger - under higher prices and
- in the long run.
5Typical non-price conservation policies
Water Rationing
Technology Standards
Outdoor watering may be restricted to a certain
number of days per week, or banned altogether.
Federal law requires low-flow plumbing fixtures
in new construction. Cities and states may also
require retrofitting.
6Water Demand and Non-price Conservation Policies
- Non-price conservation policies can reduce water
demand, though effectiveness varies. - Mandatory policies (well-enforced) have stronger
effects than voluntary policies and education. - Water savings from promoting water-conserving
fixtures may be smaller than expected, due to
behavioral responses.
7Comparing Price and Non-price Conservation
Policies
- Cost effectiveness
- Monitoring and enforcement
- Equity considerations
- Political feasibility
8Prices achieve conservation cost-effectively
- Households and firms decide how to reduce
consumption, and by how much. - Households and firms with different costs and
benefits of water use can react differently. - Water use reductions occur among users with the
lowest value for water use.
9Monitoring and Enforcement
- Non-price policies require significant monitoring
and enforcement.
How to report water cheaters Atlanta
Journal-ConstitutionOctober 19, 2007
- Cheating on a water price increase requires
that users consume water off-meter more
difficult.
10Equity Considerations
- Low-income households tend to contribute a
greater share of aggregate water demand
reductions when prices increase, in comparison to
non-price policies. - This does NOT mean that price-based approaches
are regressive. - Progressive price-based approaches can be
designed. - The equitability of non-price policies depends on
how they are financed.
11Political Feasibility
- Raising water prices is politically difficult.
- Ironically, non-price policies may be more costly
(though costs are less transparent). - Economic costs of prescriptive approach
- Utility budget deficits often require price
increases after successful non-price
conservation policies.