Title: Topics in Financial Economics Term 2, Lecture 5
1Topics in Financial Economics Term 2, Lecture 5
- Some empirical examples
- Agency
2A case study BP
3The big picture
The end result?
4(No Transcript)
5Activities that affect firm values
- Dividends change value of the asset
- Repurchases change the number of shares
outstanding (exposed to market) - Divestiture sell assets to another firm that can
use them more efficiently - Spin-off grant independence to a division
- Equity carve out make division
semi-independent parent retains controlling
interest - Tracking stock division completely controlled
(does not have own board)
6The impact and determinants of buybacks
- Version 1
- Broadcom Corp. reported a big drop in
fourth-quarter profits on costs from its recently
ended options probe, while profits before charges
were off slightly from a year earlier. The
company said Thursday its quarterly net income
was 45.1 million, down from 110.2 million a
year earlier. The results include a 50 million
charge for related to stock options. Broadcom
wrapped an internal investigation last month,
saying it would revise financial statements for
1998 to 2005 with charges of 2.2 billion for
stock option grants that were improperly
accounted for. Excluding charges, Broadcom said
it earned 185 million, down 6 from a year
earlier. Revenue for the quarter rose 12.5 to
923.5 million. Shares of Broadcom were flat in
after-hours trading. The company also said it
plans to buy back 1 billion worth of its shares
starting next week. Broadcom plans to use some of
2.8 billion in cash to fund the buyback.
Subsequently, shares rose significantly. - Version 2
- RUPERT MURDOCH, the chairman of BSkyB, hinted
yesterday that the satellite broadcaster could
resume its controversial share buyback programme
in future years. Mr Murdoch, who is also chief
executive of News Corporation, parent company of
The Times, told investors at the broadcasters
annual meeting yesterday that Sky may revisit
this subject again. A year ago Sky pledged that
it would not pursue a buyback this year, amid
investor concerns that the exercise results in
its principal shareholder, News Corporation,
gaining increasing control without submitting a
takeover bid.
7(How) Do Buybacks affect shareholders?
- Aug 03 Royal Bank of Scotland this week
became the latest group to announce the return of
surplus capital to shareholders through a stock
buyback because it cannot find a better use for
the funds. - Repurchase certainly boosts earnings per share
(EPS), a popular measure of performance - This link between buybacks and EPS has been
abused, particularly during the 1990s bubble
when investors were obsessed with EPS momentum.
It also helped senior management, whose
remuneration was commonly tied to EPS growth - Empirically, buybacks do improve shareholder
value if - Stock is purchased at the right price (GSK
repurchase at 18 of stock at 35 over true value
triggered fall to 12 but exec bonuses rose) - Needs supporting evidence of capital discipline
(Rentokil had been following 20 annual capex
growth after share value collapsed in 2000, they
bought back 35 of stock as part of a programme
of disposals and have since outperformed
market by 120) - do not sell off the components with the highest
returns - Value takes at least one year to materialise (vs.
dividends, which produce immediate effects
8Differences
Best
Worst
9Principal-agent theory
- Interaction between 2 parties one acts for the
other - Not always clear who is the agent depends on
incentives. Agent is the one who can gain by
cheating, and therefore needs incentives to
fulfil the bargain. - Problem 1 hidden action (moral hazard)
principal cannot (freely) monitor/verify agents
action - Problem 2 hidden information (adverse
selection) principal cannot test whether agents
action was justified - Also known as contract theory
- Assumes (uninformed) principal moves first
- Distinct from signalling, where informed party
moves first
10Agency reading
- Principal-agent theory
- Osborne and Rubinstein A course in game theory,
ch. 10. - D. Gale notes sec 3 http//www.econ.nyu.edu/user/g
aled/finchap03.pdf - Gale and Allen, Financial Innovation and Risk
Sharing (1994) sec. 4.1 - Stole notes secs 1.1, 2.1 (more as interest
dictates) http//gsblas.uchicago.edu/papers/lectur
es.pdf - Handa slides http//www.biz.uiowa.edu/class/6F215_
handa/Pr2lec5.ppt - Agency problems in financial economics
- Jensen, M. and W. Meckling (1976) Theory of the
firm, managerial behaviour, agency costs and
ownership structure, Journal of Financial
Economics 3, 305-360 Link from Warwick machines - Myers, S. (1977) Determinants of corporate
borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics 5,
147-175 Link from Warwick machines - Grossman, S. and O. Hart (1983) An analysis of
the principal-agent problem Econometrica 51,
7-45 Link - Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1997) A survey of
corporate governance Journal of Finance, 52,
737-783 Link from Warwick machines - Murphy, K. (1999) Executive compensation, in
Handbook of Labor Economics, O. Ashenfelter and
D. Card (eds), 2485-2563
11Simple model try a risky venture, split proceeds
- Agent takes action s in a (finite or interval)
set A - The state is w in a (finite) set W the state is
determined by a - The probability of w given a is p(wa)
- The revenue if w occurs is R(w)
- The agents utility from consuming c (bought with
his share of revenue) and taking action a is u(c,
a) we assume u(c, a) U(c) J(a) - The principals utility from her share of revenue
is V(c) - Both utilities are strictly increasing, concave,
twice continuously differentiable - We assume the agents consumption is non-negative
(liquidity or limited liability)
12Pareto optimality
- Contract (a, h(.)), where a is the contracted
action and h(w) gt 0 is the payment to the agent
in state w. - Principals problem choose contract to maximise
principals utility subject to agents
participationPP - Theorem A contract is Pareto efficient iff it
solves this problem - If the (risk-sharing) payment h is always gt 0 and
optimalB - If a is interior and p and J are differentiable
13Incentive efficiency
- If agents actions cannot be observed or
verified, they must be incentive-compatibleIC
- A contract is incentive efficient if it is Pareto
optimal relative to the set of incentive
compatible contracts. It solves the original
problem (PP) with the added IC constraint. - Any solution to this enhanced problem (PP) is
incentive efficient if the participation
constraint always binds. - To solve this problem
- Fix a and compute the payoff V(a) from providing
incentives to do a. - Now choose a to maximise V(a)
- Because U and V are concave, the first part is
easier to solve than the whole, and gives many
useful insights. If V is linear (the principal is
risk-neutral) this just minimises the expected
payment to the agent
14Does moral hazard prevent first-best?
- If the principal is risk-neutral and the agent is
strictly risk-averse, condition B implies that
payment h is independent of state, hence of
agents action. The agent will choose the
cost-minimising action and first-best can be
achieved only if the optimal action (for the
principal) is also the cheapest (for the agent). - If the principal is risk-averse and the agent is
risk-neutral, condition B implies R(w)-h(w) is
constant for interior solutions sell the firm
to the agent, providing firm remains profitable
(agent gets gt 0). - In general, there is y s.t. R(w)-h(w) miny,
r(w), and h(w) maxR(w) y, 0
15If both parties are risk-averse
- The first-order condition for the first-best
is - The first-order condition for incentive
compatibility is - The first-best and incentive-efficient contracts
only coincide if
16An example 2 states W (win) or L (lose)
- We assume winning is worthwhile R(W) gt R(L)
- The necessary condition is
- If effort is productive (i.e. pgt0), this implies
paying the agent the full marginal
contributionR(W)-R(L)h(W)-h(L) - This does not satisfy condition B unless the
agent is risk neutral on the interval h(L),
h(W).
17Optimal incentives, 1
- Assume the principal is risk-neutral (always
prefers the action with higher expected revenue
if costs are equal). - There are a finite number of states and actions,
strictly increasing revenue - The monotone likelihood ratio property (MLRP)
for any actions altb, the ratio p(w,b)/p(w,a) is
non-decreasing in w. Also assume that the vectors
p(.,b) and p(., a) are distinct (ratio sometimes
rises). Expected revenue is increasing in a.
18Optimal incentives, 2
- Because it only uses a one-sided IC constraint,
is at least as big as V. Suppose it is bigger
for some a, so the agent wants to choose more
effort but the principal will always prefer
more effort if it comes at the same price, so the
a that maximises the two V-functions will be the
same., so we can limit attention to the modified
problem. - Most incentive schemes are increasing a higher w
brings a higher h though not necessarily a
higher h(w)/R(w). Is this true of the optimal
scheme? - Rearranging the Kuhn-Tucker conditions for an
interior solution to the modified problem, we
get - By the MLRP, the RHS is non-increasing in w so
too is the LHS, hence the optimal h(w) is also
non-decreasing
19Examples
- 2 states W (win), L (lose)
- 2 projects or effort levels (A,B)
- let 0 lt pA p(W,A) lt pB p(W,B) lt 1
- Effort cost J(A) 0 lt J(B).
- U(0) reservation utility 0.
- To implement the inferior project (A), set
- h(L) hL h(W) hW 0
- Constraints to implement BICIR
20Relation between IC, IR constraints
- Can rewrite IC as
- IR implies positive consumption in at least one
state, so - Therefore, IC implies IR holds strictly (doesnt
bind) - We can thus rewrite principals problem as
21Optimum and project choice
- Clearly, optimality implies hL 0, and the
optimum level of hW satisfies pB -
pAU(hW)J(B) - What makes managerial compensation hW higher?
- Higher effort cost J(B)
- Higher managerial risk aversion U(hW) U(hL)
- Lower managerial marginal productivity pB - pA
- Optimal project compare profits from both schemes
22Incentive-efficiency example
- Set-up as before (2 states, 2 effort levels, 0
reservation utility, risk-neutral agent,
principal) - Also assume
- R(L) 0 lt R(W) revenues in 2 states
- J(A) 0 lt J(B) effort cost to 2 actions
- 0 lt pA lt pB lt 1 probability of winning state
for 2 actions - Optimal implementation
- Project A hW hL 0
- Project B hL 0 hW J(B)/pB pA
- Principals payoff V(w)
- Project A pAR(W)
- Project B pBR(W) - J(B)/pB pA
- If it happens that v(W) V(L), the contract
implementing project A solves the principals
problem, but is not incentive efficient, because
the project implementing B gives the agent
strictly higher utility.
23Corner solution example
- In previous example, the agent gets 0 in state L
regardless of which action (project, effort
level) he chooses. You might think this is due to
risk neutrality, but corner solutions are
possible even when U(0) ?. Suppose U(h) ha
for 0 lt a lt 1. - U(0) is still 0, so the optimal incentive scheme
implementing A in the above example is still h(w)
0 - To implement B, the optimal scheme is h(L) 0
and h(W) J(B)/(pB pA)(1/a) - Thus it is not always safe to simply assume
interior solutions