Protectionism: How Nations Restrict Trade - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 38
About This Presentation
Title:

Protectionism: How Nations Restrict Trade

Description:

... collected by Homeland's government is equal to the sum of areas C and Y. ... Some of this tariff revenue, area C, comes out of the free trade consumer surplus. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:41
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 39
Provided by: hendrikva
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Protectionism: How Nations Restrict Trade


1
Protectionism How Nations Restrict Trade
  • In a regime of Free Trade and free economic
    intercourse it would be of little consequence
    that iron lay on one side of a political
    frontier, and labor, coal, and blast furnaces on
    the other. But as it is, men have devised ways
    to impoverish themselves and one another and
    prefer collective animosities to individual
    happiness.
  • (John Maynard Keynes, 1920)

2
The Goals of this Chapter
  • Use both partial equilibrium and general
    equilibrium models to explain the effects of
    tariffs.
  • Use the general equilibrium model of a tariff to
    explain the important Lerner Symmetry Theorem.
  • Extend the analysis to trade quotas, and
    demonstrate the similarities between tariffs and
    quotas.
  • Describe some the many other ways in which
    governments restrict international trade.
  • Introduce the concept of rent seeking and how it
    applies to trade policy from both a static and an
    growth perspective.

3
The Economics of a Tariff
  • A tariff is simply a tax on imports
  • An ad valorem tariff is a tax that is expressed
    as a percentage of the value of the import being
    taxed
  • A specific tariff is an import tax expressed as a
    fixed dollar amount per unit of imports

4
The Economics of a Tariff
  • The economic analysis of a tariff makes use of
    the two-country partial equilibrium model of
    trade.
  • This model can be applied to trace the effects of
    a tariff on producers and consumers in the market
    for a traded good in both the exporting and
    importing countries.

5
The Economics of a Tariff
  • First, we look at the effect of a tariff on the
    importing country.
  • The domestic effects can be seen by looking at
    the two left-most diagrams in Figure 6.1.
  • That is, look just at the Homeland market and the
    International Market.

6
The Economics of a Tariff
  • Suppose an ad valorem tariff is applied to
    imports.
  • Such a tariff is illustrated in the International
    Market diagram as an increase in the supply curve
    of imports.
  • The effective decrease in foreign supply raises
    the Homeland price and reduces the quantity of
    imports.

7
The Economics of a Tariff
  • The perspective from Abroad can be illustrated in
    the center and right-most diagrams of Figure 6.1.
  • In Abroad, the tariff looks like a decrease in
    foreign demand.
  • As a result, the price in Abroad declines, and
    the volume of exports falls.

8
The Economics of a TariffThe Welfare Effects in
Homeland and Abroad
9
The Economics of a TariffThe Welfare Effects
  • Prices rise in Homeland and fall in Abroad as the
    tariff drives a wedge between what exporters
    receive and importers pay.
  • In the importing country, Homeland, consumers
    lose surplus equal to the areas AbCd.
  • In Abroad, the exporting country, producers lose
    surplus equal to the areas WxYz.

10
The Economics of a TariffThe Welfare Effects
  • The price rise in Homeland increases producer
    surplus by the area A.
  • In Abroad, the fall in the price increases
    consumer surplus by the area W.

11
The Economics of a TariffThe Welfare Effects
  • Both countries suffer deadweight losses from the
    tariff because the volume of trade is reduces and
    prices are distorted.
  • Homeland loses areas bd
  • Abroad loses areas xz.
  • The deadweight losses are equal to the same
    colored areas in the center International Market
    diagram.

12
The Economics of a TariffThe Welfare Effects
  • Total tariff revenue collected by Homelands
    government is equal to the sum of areas C and Y.
  • Some of this tariff revenue, area C, comes out of
    the free trade consumer surplus.
  • The rest of the tariff revenue comes out of the
    free trade producer surplus, namely area Y.

13
The two-country partial equilibrium model shows
that a tariff by one country on the others
exports causes
  • A transfer of welfare from domestic consumers to
    domestic producers in the importing country.
  • A transfer of welfare from producers to
    consumers in the exporting country.
  • A transfer of consumer surplus in the importing
    country to the importing country government in
    the form of tariff revenue.
  • A transfer of producer surplus in the exporting
    country to the government of the importing
    country.
  • Deadweight losses in both importing and
    exporting countries.

14
Example 6.2The Gains and Losses from a Tariff
  • Example 6.2 shows the welfare effects of a 3
    specific tariff in a market that imports 8
    million calculators with free trade.
  • The welfare effects consist of changes in
    consumer surplus, producer surplus, and tariff
    revenue.

15
Example 6.2The Gains and Losses from a Tariff
  • For Homeland, the welfare effects of shifting
    from free trade in calculators to a 3 specific
    tariff are as follows
  • Homeland Consumer Surplus (AbCd)
    18.75 million
  • Homeland Producer Surplus (A)
    11.25 million
  • Homeland Govt Tariff Revenue (CY)
    6.00 million
  • Net Welfare Change Ybd 1.50 million

16
Example 6.2The Gains and Losses from a Tariff
  • Abroad suffers a net loss that exceeds Homelands
    net gain by the total deadweight losses in both
    countries
  • Abroads Consumer Surplus (W) 11.25
    million
  • Abroads Producer Surplus (WxYz)
    18.75 million
  • Net Change Y x z 7.50 million
  • The net loss for the world is
  • World deadweight losses (bdxz) 9.0
    million

17
How Much Protection Does a Tariff Really Provide?
  • The true protection that a tariff provides to an
    industry is more accurately stated in terms of
    the industrys value added.
  • An effective tariff measures a nominal tariffs
    effect on the value added of an industry.
  • For example, if a tariff raises the price of a
    final good by 20 percent, and the industry adds
    half the products value, the effective tariff is
    40 percent.

18
How Much Protection Does a Tariff Really Provide?
  • A tariff on intermediate products can reduce an
    industrys value added.
  • That is, an effective tariff can be negative.
  • In the example, if a government imposes a tariff
    on inputs while imposing no tariff on the final
    product, then the producers of final products
    will find their value added squeezed from 5,000
    to 4,000.

19
The Economics of a Quota
  • The effects of a quota can be illustrated using
    the partial equilibrium model of imports and
    exports.
  • Suppose the quota is set at half the free trade
    quantity of imports.
  • From Homeland, the foreign supply curve looks
    like the kinked curve in the International Market
    on the right.
  • With restricted imports, the Homeland price rises.

20
The Economics of a Quota
  • From Abroads perspective, the quota creates a
    kinked foreign demand curve in the International
    Market.
  • The domestic price in Abroad falls as the
    quantity exported is reduced to the quota level.

21
The Economics of a QuotaThe Full Welfare Effects
  • By raising the price in Homeland, the quota
    increases Homeland producers surplus by the area
    A.
  • In Abroad, the price falls and consumers gain
    surplus equal to the area W.

22
The Economics of a QuotaThe Full Welfare Effects
  • The price rise in Homeland, the importing
    country, reduces consumer surplus by the areas
    AbCd.
  • In Abroad, the price decline there reduces
    producer surplus by the areas WxYz.

23
The Economics of a QuotaThe Full Welfare Effects
  • The quota distorts prices and changes quantities
    from free trade levels, causing deadweight loses.
  • In Homeland, the deadweight losses are bd, equal
    to the same colored area in the center diagram.
  • In Abroad, deadweight losses are xz.

24
The Economics of a QuotaThe Full Welfare Effects
  • The fundamental difference between a tariff and a
    quota is that a quota generates quota rent, not
    government revenue.
  • This quota rent comes out of consumer surplus
    (area C) in the importing country and producer
    surplus (area Y) in the exporting country.

25
Example 6.3The Gains and Losses from a Quota
  • Example 6.3 shows the welfare effects of imposing
    quota of 2 million calculators on a market that
    imports 8 million calculators with free trade.
  • The welfare effects consist of changes in
    consumer surplus, producer surplus, and quota
    rent.

26
Example 6.3The Gains and Losses from a Quota
  • If the rent accrues to domestic importers
  • Homeland Consumer Surplus (AbCd)
    18.75 million
  • Homeland Producer Surplus (A) 11.25
    million
  • Homeland Quota Rent (CY) 6.0
    million
  • Net Change Ybd 1.5 million

27
Example 6.3The Gains and Losses from a Quota
  • Abroads Consumer Surplus (W) 11.25
    million
  • Abroads Producer Surplus (WxYz)
    18.75 million
  • Abroads Quota Rent 0 0.0 million
  • Net Change Yxz 7.5 million
  • World deadweight losses (bdxz) 9.0
    million

28
Example 6.3The Gains and Losses from a Quota
  • If the rent from Homelands quota accrues to
    foreign exporters
  • Homeland Consumer Surplus (AbCd)
    18.75 million
  • Homeland Producer Surplus (A)
    11.25 million
  • Homeland Quota Rent 0 0.0
    million
  • Net Change Ybd 7.5 million

29
Example 6.3The Gains and Losses from a Quota
  • Abroads Consumer Surplus (W)
    11.25 million
  • Abroads Producer Surplus (WxYz)
    18.75 million
  • Abroads Quota Rent (CY) 6.0 million
  • Net Change (Yxz) 1.5 million
  • World deadweight losses (bdxz) 9.0
    million

30
The Precise Welfare Effects of an Import Quota
Depend on Who Gets the Rent
  • When Abroads exporters are able to raise their
    prices and capture the quota rent, Abroads
    overall welfare loss is smaller, 1.5 million
    rather than 7.5 million.
  • If it is importers that purchase overseas at
    lowered world prices and sell domestically at the
    higher prices, then Homeland gains the quota rent
    and reduces its overall welfare loss from the
    imposing the quota.
  • Who ultimately gains the quota rent depends on
    who collects the difference between the higher
    price in Homeland and the lower price in Abroad.

31
The Equivalence of Tariffs and Quotas
  • There is an equivalent tariff for any given
    quota, and vice versa.
  • The areas representing transfers from one group
    to another and deadweight losses seem to be the
    same for equivalent tariffs and quotas.
  • The only exception is the area C, which
    represents tariff revenue in the case of the
    tariff and quota rent in the case of the quota.

32
Some Differences between Tariffs and Quotas
  • If demand shifts out, a tariff and quota that
    were equivalent will come to have very different
    price and welfare effects.
  • Under a tariff, an increase in demand creates a
    new market equilibrium at c.
  • Under a quota, an increase in demand creates a
    new market equilibrium at d.

33
Some Differences between Tariffs and Quotas
  • Under a tariff, the price rises to to Pt, under a
    quota it rises to Pq.
  • Under a tariff, the quantity imported rises from
    a to b, under a quota imports are unchanged.
  • An increase in demand results in a greater gain
    in consumer surplus under a tariff.
  • Deadweight loss is also less under a tariff,
    compare the smaller blue triangle with the
    quotas red triangle.

34
Some Differences between Tariffs and Quotas
  • A quota may also not ration rent opportunities as
    efficiently as a tariff.
  • Consumers and producers along the green portions
    of the demand and supply curves should
    participate in the restricted trade.
  • A quota could result in people at point B below
    the free trade price Pf getting import permits.
  • Or, import permits may be denied to the
    lowest-cost suppliers and instead given to
    high-cost producers at point D.

35
The Costs of Costly Rent Seeking
  • The costs of the resources used in rent seeking
    must be added to the costs of protection.
  • Potential importers would be willing to spend
    some of the potential quota rent C to lobby
    policymakers to get the rent.
  • If lobbying activities consume resources equal in
    value to half of the area C, then the total costs
    to the economy of the quota of bc would be equal
    to the deadweight losses bd plus the blue half
    of C.

36
The Costs of Costly Rent Seeking
  • Potential importers are not the only ones who
    engage in rent seeking.
  • Consumers may wish to organize to protect
    themselves against rent-seeking producers.
  • Consumers would be willing to spend up to the
    lost consumer surplus (AbCd) to avoid the
    quota altogether.
  • If lobbying costs consume half of the area A,
    then the darkly shaded area must also be added to
    the costs of protection.

37
Dynamic Rent Seeking Obstructing Creative
Destruction
  • For the process of creative destruction to
    work, there must be destruction as well as
    creation.
  • In a Schumpeterian environment of innovative
    competition, lobbying for protection against
    foreign competition may be motivated not by
    producers desire to increase producer surplus,
    but by the desire to slow the process of creative
    destruction and extend the period during which
    domestic innovators can reap profits.
  • If such dynamic rent is successful,
    technological progress will slow, and welfare
    gains from economic growth will be lost.

38
Dynamic Rent Seeking Obstructing Creative
Destruction
  • The welfare costs of obstructive dynamic rent
    seeking and the protection that it induces are
    potentially very large.
  • The costs of dynamic rent seeking activity
    include the resources that are spent on
    obstructive activity rather than on the
    production of welfare-enhancing output.
  • There are also the opportunity costs of lost
    future economic growth if the obstruction of
    competitive innovation is successful.
  • Given the power of compounding, the opportunity
    cost of obstructing innovative activity can be
    enormous because the power of compounding
    magnifies even small changes in growth rates into
    large welfare changes.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com