EEHCStrategy - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

EEHCStrategy

Description:

1. PROPERTY RATES BILL: dplg RESPONSE TO QUESTIONS POSED BY ... ARGUMENTS FOR BASE ... Despite the vehement opposition to a tax on rural land by ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:28
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 94
Provided by: daniej
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: EEHCStrategy


1

PROPERTY RATES BILL dplg RESPONSE TO QUESTIONS
POSED BY PORTFOLIO COMMITTEE ON PROVINCIAL AND
LOCAL GOVERNMENT November 18, 2003


2
MAIN ISSUES TO BE RESOLVED
  • Choice of Rates Base
  • land and improvements or land only?
  • Choice of Rating System
  • uniform or variable?
  • Constitutionality of Exclusions
  • Public Service Infrastructure
  • Protected Areas
  • Rating of Agricultural Land
  • Religious, Welfare and Charitable, Independent
    Schools

3
CHOICE OF RATES BASE
  • With regard to the base
  • Why have we chosen to rate land and improvements
    versus land only?

4
ARGUMENTS FOR BASE BEING LAND ONLY
  • If only land is rated, owner will have incentive
    to develop land to fullest use
  • Counter argument
  • Little quantitative evidence
  • Several other factors that affect land
    development - no empirical evidence to support
    that property rates play major role
  • Issues such as comfort, space, investment play
    major role

5
ARGUMENTS FOR BASE BEING LAND ONLY
  • Cost of valuation process is lower
  • Counter argument
  • Same number of properties have to be valued
    regardless of the base
  • Valuing land and improvements together is
    administratively easier and more objective - more
    sales data available

6
ARGUMENTS FOR BASE BEING LAND ONLY
  • Land rating has a strong relation to notion of
    public good
  • Counter argument
  • Assumes that land is largely undeveloped and that
    State controls most of land - not true in South
    Africa

7
ARGUMENTS FOR LAND AND IMPROVEMENTS
  • Provide more comprehensive measure of affluence
    so likely to be more progressive
  • Easier to assess than land only
  • More sales data available
  • Total property value is concept most property
    owners understand

8
ARGUMENTS FOR LAND AND IMPROVEMENTS
  • Politically more acceptable
  • Lower nominal rate needed to generate same
    revenue
  • Current practice shows that two-thirds of
    municipalities have historically included land
    and improvements in their rates base
  • Administrative costs will not be prohibitive
  • To the extent that there is a trend in developing
    countries is towards improved value

9
TREND IN OECD COUNTRIES
10
TREND IN CENTRAL EASTERN EUROPE
11
TREND IN LATIN AMERICA
12
TREND IN CARIBBEAN
13
TREND IN ASIA
14
TREND IN AFRICA
15
RESULTS FROM dplg CASE STUDIES
  • Property rates base and total amount collected in
    rates will increase as a result of base shifting
    from land only to land and improvements
  • 7 in Greater Tzaneen
  • 5 in Matjhabeng
  • 20 in Mbombela
  • 48 in Ulundi

16
RESULTS FROM dplg CASE STUDIES
  • Increase in rates income will be used to reduce
    rates burden on current ratepayers, particularly
    in the residential sector
  • Residential sectors share of property rates will
    fall
  • From 70.6 to 50.4 in Ulundi
  • From 56.7 to 39.4 in Phokwane
  • From 34.4 to 29 in Mbombela

17
RESULTS FROM CITY OF CAPE TOWN STUDY
  • If rates base were changed from land and
    improvements to land only
  • Residential properties would have borne a higher
    incidence of rates than commercial properties
  • Share of residential properties would have
    increased from 30 to 55
  • Within each residential and commercial area,
    shift would have occurred from properties with
    high-value improvements to those with little or
    no improvements

18
CONCLUSIONS FROM STUDIES
  • Residential sector will bear smaller proportion
    of total rates bill relative to commercial sector
  • Poorer property owners will bear a smaller
    proportion of total rates bill relative to
    wealthier owners
  • Rates base and rates revenue for municipalities
    will be optimised
  • Results comply with governments national
    objectives and White Paper on Local Government

19
CHOICE OF RATING SYSTEM
  • With regard to the rate
  • Why mandate a uniform rate (same rate on land and
    improvements) and not a variable rate?

20
REASONS FOR UNIFORM RATE
  • Determine fiscal capacity of municipalities
  • Enable national monitoring and prescription
  • Achieve equitable treatment of citizens
  • Easier for people to understand and engage in
    rates policy consultation process

21
REASONS FOR UNIFORM RATE
  • If we allow for variable rate
  • Some municipalities might opt for zero rating
    improvements tantamount to the base being land
    only i.e. a non-uniform base that we have already
    argued against
  • Valuers will have to arrive at separate values
    for land and improvements - subjective and will
    not realise optimal revenue base

22
RESULTS FROM dplg CASE STUDIES
  • Ethekwini
  • Rates land and improvements at uniform rate for
    residential property but at variable rates for
    commercial, industrial, government and
    non-industrial
  • If it rates land and improvements at a uniform
    rate, rates burden on residential properties will
    fall
  • Rates burden will fall for low value and increase
    for high value residential property

23
RESULTS FROM dplg CASE STUDIES
  • Phokwane
  • Rates land and improvements at different rates
  • If it rates land and improvements at a uniform
    rate on all properties, rates burden on
    residential properties will fall from 56.7 to
    39.4
  • Rates burden will fall for all classes of
    residential property

24
CONCLUSIONS FROM STUDIES
  • If we have a uniform rate instead of a variable
    rate
  • Rates burden will be lower for residential than
    for commercial sector
  • Low-value residential property owners will pay
    less than high-value residential property owners
    - more equitable
  • Will enable newly emerging middle class to afford
    property since their relative rates burden will
    be lower that that for the rich

25
CONSTITUTIONALITY OF EXCLUSIONS
  • Is there any constitutional basis for the
    exclusion of property from the municipal rates
    base?
  • Can Section 229 (2) of the Constitution be used
    to exclude property rather than to regulate it?
  • Can the framework in clause 3 (3) of the Property
    Rates Bill be used to create mandatory
    exemptions?
  • Is everything in clause 15 (2) of the Property
    Rates Bill consistent with Section 229 (2) (a) of
    the Constitution?

26
CONSTITUTIONAL BASIS FOR EXCLUSION
  • Section 229 (2) (b) of the Constitution provides
    the constitutional basis for exclusion since the
    term regulate includes the power to describe
    circumstances under which a municipality would
    not be entitled to impose property rates

27
CONSTITUTIONAL BASIS FOR EXCLUSION
  • The constitutionality of this power to exclude
    would depend on whether or not such a limit or
    restriction violates Section 151 (4) of the
    Constitution
  • The national or a provincial government may not
    compromise or impede a municipalitys ability or
    right to exercise its powers or perform its
    functions.

28
CONSTITUTIONAL BASIS FOR EXCLUSION
  • Section 229 (2) (a) of the Constitution cannot be
    used to exclude property - only when a
    municipality has exercised its power can a
    question arise as to whether or not it has
    violated Section 229 (2) (a)

29
USE OF 3(3) TO CREATE MANDATORY EXEMPTIONS
  • The national framework in 3 (3) cannot be used to
    create mandatory exemptions
  • Only Parliament has the power to exclude - not
    the Minister

30
CONSISTENCY OF 15 (2) WITH SECTION 229 (2) (a)
  • Given that 229 (2) (a) cannot be used to justify
    exclusions, the consistency of 15 (2) is not an
    issue
  • Legal opinion recommends that 15 (2) be delinked
    from 15 (1)
  • Are exclusions in 15 (2) consistent with 151 (4)
    of the Constitution?
  • Impact would vary from one municipality to
    another so must be very careful when specifying
    exclusions

31
PUBLIC SERVICE INFRASTRUCTURE
  • Does the public service infrastructure benefit
    the public directly?
  • Should structures be taken out of the definition?
  • How do we deal with State-owned vis-a-vis
    privately owned?
  • What is current practice with regard to rating of
    public service infrastructure as defined in the
    Bill?
  • Recommendations for treatment of public service
    infrastructure

32
BENEFIT TO PUBLIC
  • Only infrastructure that benefits the public
    directly must be included in the definition
  • Thus, ancillary infrastructure, which is part of
    the cost of doing business (e.g. railway lines
    used by Eskom to transport goods) should not be
    excluded from rates
  • Must remember that any exclusion deprives
    municipality of much-needed revenue and may
    violate Section 151 (4) of the Constitution

33
TREATMENT OF STRUCTURES
  • Structures that house the infrastructure are
    improvements and hence should be rated
  • Decision made to take out power stations and
    substations out of part (c) of definition

34
STATE-OWNED VIS-A-VIS PRIVATELY OWNED
  • Level of State ownership - Eskom and Transnet
    100 State owned, Telkom only 41
  • Do enterprise make a profit? If State owned
    enterprises are given preferential treatment for
    rates purposes, how does this affect equitable
    treatment of competitors?
  • Tariffs of Eskom and Telkom are independently
    regulated not so for Transnet
  • Eskom, Transnet and Telkom pay income tax - so
    rates are deductible as a cost of doing business
  • Decision that only State-owned infrastructure
    should be considered

35
CURRENT MUNICIPAL PRACTICE
  • SALGA canvassed municipalities on current and
    preferred treatment of public service
    infrastructure
  • General position of 5 municipalities who
    presented on August 13, 2003
  • Public service infrastructure forms an important
    source of rates revenue
  • Any exemptions should be at the discretion of
    municipalities

36
CURRENT MUNICIPAL PRACTICE
  • dplg conducted subsequent survey in August 2003
  • Survey questionnaires sent to 23 municipalities
  • 14 municipalities are not rating any components

37
CURRENT MUNICIPAL PRACTICE
  • 9 municipalities are currently rating some of the
    aspects of public service infrastructure such as
    power stations and substations, runways and
    aprons, telecommunication towers, water supply
    reservoirs, and servitudes
  • 2 municipalities indicated that exclusions would
    have a significant negative impact (Moses Kotane
    would lose about 5 while the City of Cape Town
    0.95 of its rtaes revenue) 7 municipalities
    said it would not impact negatively.

38
RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Define publicly controlled in the Bill
  • Owned by or otherwise under the control of the
    state, including
  • A public entity listed in the PFMA
  • A municipality or
  • A municipal entity as defined in the Structures
    Act

39
RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Change definition of public service
    infrastructure in the Bill
  • Publicly controlled infrastructure of the
    following kinds
  • Roads
  • Water or sewer schemes serving the public
  • Electricity schemes serving the public
  • Schemes for transporting gas or liquid fuels
  • National railway system
  • Runways or aprons at international, national or
    provincial airports
  • Waterways at harbours
  • Rights of way, easements and servitudes in
    connection with the above

40
RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Only public service infrastructure connected with
    the provision of free basic services (water,
    sanitation and electricity) should be given
    special consideration
  • ALL public service infrastructure should be
    valued at a national level to ensure uniformity
    and consistency of valuations
  • Values apportioned to each municipality who is
    then free to rate infrastructure as it sees fit
  • Exception Basic service infrastructure whose
    value will be reduced

41
PROTECTED AREAS
  • Sub-Committee agreed to exclude privately owned
    land declared as a protected area in terms of the
    Protected Areas Act
  • Agreement reached that exclusion would remain
    until protected area is de-proclaimed
  • Arrear rates on privately owned de-proclaimed
    land to be levied to base date of valuation cycle
    where
  • Property owner withdraws from agreement
  • Minister has cancelled agreement due to breach of
    contract by owner
  • Term developed or used to be retained

42
RATING OF AGRICULTURAL LAND
  • What is the rationale for rating the agricultural
    sector given the concerns raised by KWANALU, Katz
    Commission and independent expert?

43
RATING OF AGRICULTURAL LAND
  • Summary of concerns raised by agricultural sector
    in public submissions
  • Rating agricultural land will lead to a drop in
    value of agricultural land
  • The definition of improved value is ambiguous
    in relation to farmland (not necessarily the same
    as market value)
  • Use value versus improved value

44
RATING OF AGRICULTURAL LAND
  • Summary of concerns (cont.)
  • Level of taxation is quite high (2) and main
    trading partners do not rate agricultural land or
    rate it at low levels
  • Farmers are already being taxed (RSC levies) and
    their tax burden will increase, affecting
    international competitiveness
  • Municipalities deliver virtually no services to
    farmland - 38 functions provided by them mostly
    benefit urban dwellers

45
RATING OF AGRICULTURAL LAND
  • Summary of concerns (cont.)
  • Property rates on agriculture will impact
    negatively on between 5 and 8 desired outcomes
    of the Strategic Plan on Agriculture
  • Privately owned conservation and protected land
    should be excluded from property rates
  • Possibility of deferred rates in the event of
    natural disasters

46
KATZ COMMISSION RECOMMENDATIONS
47
BACKGROUND
  • Katz Commission appointed in 1995 to consider
    introduction of land tax in South Africa
  • Subcommittee presented initial report in November
    1995
  • Despite the vehement opposition to a tax on rural
    land by organised agriculture, mining and
    hospitality industries, Subcommittee was of
    opinion that such objections are best heard at
    the local level, where consideration of level of
    services to be provided from proceeds of the tax
    can be fully accounted for

48
RECOMMENDATION
  • Katz Commission supported recommendation that,
    although a rural land tax should not be levied at
    a national level, in principle, such a tax at
    local government level should be given serious
    consideration
  • Sufficient international experience on
    implementation and administration of such a tax
  • Imposition would not represent a new tax in South
    Africa had been previously levied by former
    Cape Province on divisional council level (and
    subsequently in all provinces at local council
    level)

49
KATZ COMMISSION RATIONALE FOR LAND TAX
  • Rural land tax
  • Has potential to raise revenue for rural
    municipalities
  • Will give greater fiscal autonomy to rural
    municipalities
  • Will seek to entrench horizontal equity
    principles in taxation since urban dwellers
    liable for property rates

50
FURTHER INVESTIGATION
  • Katz Commission mandated further investigation
    and Subcommittee presented further findings in
    August1998
  • Findings were presented in the interim phase of
    local government transformation

51
KATZ COMMISSION MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Tax status of rural rates
  • Subcommittee recommended that rural property
    rates be a provisional income tax payment
  • Katz Commission, however, recommended that rural
    property rates be deductible for income tax
    purposes
  • Neutrality and horizontal equity require that tax
    treatment of rural property rates be similar to
    urban property rates

52
KATZ COMMISSION MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Tax base
  • Katz Commission recommended that
  • All land within municipal boundaries must be
    included in tax base
  • Tax base should exclude mineral and water rights
  • Tax base should be improved value (land and
    improvements)

53
KATZ COMMISSION MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Tax rate
  • Katz Commission recommended uniform rate on
    improved value of land
  • Tax rate and desirability of rate-capping
  • Katz Commission recommended that there should be
    no setting of the tax rate or rate-capping in
    legislation in the interest of allowing rural
    municipalities to play the role envisaged for
    them in the Constitution

54
KATZ COMMISSION MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Method of valuation
  • Subcommittee recommended that tax be based on use
    value rather than market value
  • Katz Commission, however, is of opinion that
    market value is a more certain and equitable
    method of valuation than use value

55
KATZ COMMISSION MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS
  • Tax relief measures
  • Katz Commission recommended that guidelines
    should be provided regarding
  • Types of tax relief measures that are allowable
    and
  • Conditions under which such measures may be
    implemented (such as prescriptions for more
    transparent and participative processes)
  • Experience has shown that exemptions, rebates and
    tax deferrals should be kept to an absolute
    minimum

56
CONCERNS RAISED BY AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN PUBLIC
SUBMISSIONS
57
CONCERN
  • Rating agricultural land will lead to a drop in
    value of agricultural land
  • 1 property rate on agricultural land will lead
    to a 16 to 20 reduction in land values
  • 5 property rate would reduce land value to 20
    or make land worthless
  • Therefore, agriculture recommend a maximum rate
    of 0.5 on improved value of farmland as this
    would reduce land values by between 8 and 10.

58
dplg RESPONSE
  • Problems with assumptions
  • Assumes very high rate of capitalisation (80 to
    100). Studies have found wide-ranging rate
  • Oates (1969) 66
  • Edel and Sclar (1974) 50
  • Reinhard (1981) 31
  • Palman and Smith (1998) 63
  • Shapiro et al (1999) 20
  • Katz Commission assumes a 26.5 rate of
    capitalisation.

59
dplg RESPONSE
  • Problems with assumptions (cont.)
  • Assumes cause and effect relationship between
    property rates and fall in land values. Other
    factors, such as location, productivity of land,
    proximity to infrastructure and amenities, also
    affect land values
  • Ignores the fact that municipal expenditure on
    services in the area may actually lead to land
    values going up

60
dplg RESPONSE
  • Problems with assumptions (cont.)
  • Rental return is a static ratio which is used to
    capture the effect of a dynamic situation in
    which income and costs change over time
  • Ignores key variables such as
  • Rate of inflation
  • Rate of growth of cost and revenue streams
    associated with property (costs of doing
    business)
  • Rate of income taxation
  • Tax deductibility of property rates

61
CONCLUSION
  • The serious problems with assumptions do not
    justify maximum limit of 0.5
  • Besides, Katz Commission recommended that there
    should be no rate-setting or capping at the
    national level

62
CONCLUSION
  • Also, there are sufficient clauses in the Bill
    that protect key sectors like agriculture and
    mining
  • Minister, with concurrence of Minister of
    Finance, can limit the rate or growth in rate of
    categories of property
  • Minister can prescribe a ratio between
    residential and non-residential property
  • In addition, any exemptions and rebates granted
    to agricultural sector will have to be borne by
    other property rate payers. Municipalities are
    best placed to determine these trade-offs

63
CONCERN
  • Use value as opposed to market value as a method
    of valuation for agricultural land

64
dplg RESPONSE
  • The main disjuncture between use value and market
    value for agricultural land arises in the case of
    peri-urban areas.
  • In other cases, use value is the same as market
    value
  • If you apply market value in peri-urban areas, it
    will lead to better utilisation of land
  • Market value is used as method of valuation for
    determining capital gains tax

65
CONCERN
  • The definition of the term improved value is
    ambiguous in relation to farmland
  • Improved value for farmland is not the same as
    market value (which includes the value of
    standing crops)
  • Value of standing crops should, therefore, not be
    included in value of property

66
dplg RESPONSE
  • The method of valuation is market value.
  • This implies that the value of annual crops and
    growing timber will not be considered in
    determining the value of the land

67
VALUATION OF AGRICULTURAL PROPERTY
  • There is generally accepted valuation practice to
    arrive at the market value for agricultural land
  • If one legislates that vineyards, orchards etc.
    should not be considered in the valuation of
    agricultural property, then one would be
    departing from market value and it would be
    tantamount to arriving at land value for that
    piece of agricultural property
  • The method of valuation for the capital gains tax
    is market value vineyards and orchards are
    considered in the determination of market value
    but annual crops and growing timber are not

68
PROPOSED WORDING
  • In determining the market value of an
    agricultural property, the value of any annual
    crops and growing timber on the property that
    have not yet been harvested as at the date of
    valuation must be disregarded.

69
CONCERN
  • Level of taxation is quite high (2) and our main
    trading partners do not rate agricultural land or
    rate it at low levels.
  • This negatively influences our ability to compete
    internationally

70
dplg RESPONSE
  • Independent expert acknowledges that developing
    countries rate agriculture
  • Issue of competitiveness is acknowledged but this
    has to be dealt with at a national level - cannot
    make this a local problem
  • National government dealing with this in WTO
    negotiations
  • Katz Commission has shown that a 2 tax on land
    will reduce land values by only 12.32 (compared
    to KWANALUs 32 to 40).

71
CONCERN
  • Farmers are already being taxed through the RSC
    levy and their tax burden will increase with the
    introduction of property rates on farmland
  • This will again affect international
    competitiveness

72
dplg RESPONSE
  • Farmers are not the only ones who pay the RSC
    levy all other sectors pay not only the RSC levy
    but also property rates
  • In fact, some parts of the agricultural sector
    have received favourable treatment with regard to
    property rates because some farms were outside
    municipal boundaries other farms have
    historically been rated

73
dplg RESPONSE
  • It is imperative that all property owners are
    part of the property rates system and contribute
    equitably to financing local government
    activities
  • Municipalities, in particular rural ones, have
    huge developmental challenges and property rates
    are important for sustainable development in
    these areas

74
CONCERN
  • Municipalities deliver virtually no services to
    majority of inhabitants on farmland
  • Farmers sometimes provide many of these services
    themselves
  • 38 functions to be provided by municipalities are
    largely to the benefit of urban dwellers

75
dplg RESPONSE
  • Property rates are not tariffs they are the most
    important source of general revenue to
    municipalities
  • Revenue is used to provide services that benefit
    the community as a whole as opposed to individual
    households - firefighting services, building and
    operating clinics, parks and recreational
    facilities, funding municipal administration and
    costs of governance

76
dplg RESPONSE
  • It is not only urban areas that have access to
    these services farmers access these as well
  • Also, farmers make use of towns that act as
    service centres and benefit from overall
    infrastructure provided in towns

77
dplg RESPONSE
  • The provision of housing, health and basic
    services is essential for productivity of
    farmworkers which translates into increased
    productivity on farms and consequently profits
    for farmers

78
dplg RESPONSE
  • One should not assume that the whole agricultural
    sector is a homogeneous entity in this regard
  • In some farms, owners provide good services and
    treat workers well but this is not the case
    across the country
  • Many articles, including article in Natal Witness
    (September 3, 2003) draw attention to human
    rights abuse on farms

79
dplg RESPONSE
  • Complaints ranged from illegal evictions to lack
    of social services, lack of access to health
    care, education and so on
  • Municipalities face problems in accessing farms
    because they are private property
  • Farmers can participate in the community
    consultation process and apply for rebates on
    good cause

80
CONCERN
  • Property rates on agriculture will impact
    negatively on between 5 and 8 of desired outcomes
    of the Strategic Plan on Agriculture

81
dplg RESPONSE
  • Other taxes such as income taxes and VAT also
    have this effect
  • The issue is not whether or not property rates
    will have this effect but whether or not they
    materially and unreasonably prejudice national
    economic policies
  • In any event, we can no longer use Section 229
    (2) (a) of Constitution to justify exclusions

82
CONCERN
  • Privately owned conservation and protected land
    should be excluded from property rates

83
dplg RESPONSE
  • Some, but not all privately owned protected land
    should be excluded
  • Danger of excluding all land proclaimed by
    national or provincial legislation
  • Might lead to discernible impact on rates base
    for municipalities

84
dplg RESPONSE
  • Only land declared in terms of national (not
    provincial) legislation for the following
    purposes should be excluded (provided it meets
    national norms and standards)
  • Special nature reserves
  • National parks
  • Nature reserves (only some categories)

85
CONCERN
  • How do you deal with natural disasters and
    climatic conditions that are beyond the control
    of farmers drought, floods, etc.?

86
dplg RESPONSE
  • Allow for the possibility of deferred rates by
    explicitly providing for it in clause 23 (1) (b)

87
CONCLUSIONS
  • Agricultural sector should not be excluded from
    property rates
  • No limits should be imposed on property rates for
    agriculture
  • Definition of market value should be clarified in
    legislation to avoid confusion
  • Deferred rates should be explicitly provided for
    in legislation
  • Consideration of agricultural sector in rates
    policy of municipalities

88
CONCLUSIONS
  • Agricultural sector should not be excluded from
    property rates
  • No limits should be imposed on property rates for
    agriculture
  • Definition of market value should be clarified in
    legislation to avoid confusion
  • Deferred rates should be explicitly provided for
    in legislation
  • Consideration of agricultural sector in rates
    policy of municipalities

89
DECISIONS TAKEN BY SUB-COMMITTEE
  • No exclusions for agriculture
  • Method of valuation
  • Existing use No
  • Market value Yes
  • Given that method of valuation is market value
  • Annual crops and growing timber not considered in
    valuation
  • Vineyards, orchards considered in valuation
  • No tax rate setting or capping consider
    provision that representatives from particular
    sector can approach Minister

90
DECISIONS TAKEN BY SUB-COMMITTEE
  • Consider workers accommodation and schools and
    services provided by farmers in rates policy of
    municipalities for rebate purposes
  • Newly rateable property consider including
    property formerly outside municipal boundaries
    before December 5, 2000
  • Yes to tax deferment but no to national
    exclusions in case of natural disasters (taken
    care of by national policy)
  • Bona-fide farmers More information needed

91
RELIGIOUS, WELFARE AND CHARITABLE, INDEPENDENT
SCHOOLS
  • Places of worship and residence of minister
    excluded
  • Definition of welfare and charitable legally
    problematic hence change to include some public
    benefit activities (welfare and humanitarian,
    health care, education and development) performed
    by PBOs
  • One year grace period to be granted to
    organisations that conduct the above public
    benefit activities and are currently exempt from
    rating

92
RELIGIOUS, WELFARE AND CHARITABLE, INDEPENDENT
SCHOOLS
  • Consideration needs to be given to including
    these categories of property in Clause 8 of the
    Bill
  • No exclusions for independent schools will be
    considered in rating policy
  • All agreements reached in all Subcommittees are
    tentative pending review in Committee

93
  • THE END
  • THANK YOU
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com