Bureaucracy versus Indians - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Bureaucracy versus Indians

Description:

According to the special interest theory of politics, ... PowerPoint Presentation ... Leasing Allowed Decline in Indian Land PowerPoint Presentation ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:264
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 59
Provided by: mcart
Learn more at: https://webs.wofford.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Bureaucracy versus Indians


1
Bureaucracy versus Indians
  • Chapter 5
  • AI_12_13

2
After Surrender
  • With defeat came political and bureaucratic
    control.
  • The rise of the standing army dramatically
    changed the interface between Indians and whites,
    but it was only the tip of the bureaucratic
    iceberg that came to dominate the lives of
    Indians.

3
The Battlefield Moves to Washington
  • Once relegated to reservations, Indians struggled
    to adjust it was either adapt or perish.
  • Many Indians died from white man's diseases and
    from starvation, but others adapted.
  • Familiar with owning and herding horses, the
    Blackfeet began accumulating individually owned
    but communally herded cattle.
  • When the federal bureaucracy did finally begin
    to try to control reservation life, "the
    tradition of individual ownership was so well
    established that Indians resisted government
    efforts to establish commonly owned herds from
    1910 to 1920."

4
Wards of the State
  • From an early date, Congress and the Supreme
    Court contended that tribes were to be treated as
    sovereigns, but Indians became wards of the state
    with politicians and bureaucrats in Washington,
    D.C., acting as their trustees.
  • Not surprisingly, the effect has not always been
    maximization of Indian welfare.
  • But it has surely meant the growth of the
    bureaucracy, as can be seen in Table 5.1.

5
Bureaucratic Growth
6
Battle over Property Rights Did Not End
  • Shifted from violent warfare to political
    competition
  • For much of the next century, the Indians lost
    these battles too
  • Property rights were altered due to the demands
    of politically powerful groups and the discretion
    of the large bureaucracy that emerged to
    implement federal Indian policy.
  • Institutional change was forced on the tribes.

7
Adaptation
  • Even during the early years of allotment when the
    government was assigning parcels of land to
    individual Indians, "relative security of legal
    title created an opportunity for enterprising
    individuals to regain a limited degree of
    independence from the ration list.

8
Institutional Change
  • Farming and ranching also gave ambitious men an
    opportunity to accumulate wealth outside the
    Bureau of Indian Affairs' patronage system and,
    through sharing and gifting, to establish
    themselves as autonomous leaders.
  • However, when the government imposed new
    institutions on the Indians, agricultural
    productivity suffered because politicization of
    the institutions exhibited a blatant disregard
    for existing and past cultural norms.

9
Traditional Plains Indian Institutions
  • An open-ended meritocracy with many gently
    competing poles of authority.
  • Individual freedom was ensured by the
    representation of all families in council and by
    the requirement of consensus for national action.
  • Equally important was the nature of the economy,
    which rewarded coordination but did not make it
    necessary for survival.
  • Even the smallest family, functioning as a
    cooperative economic unit, could provide for
    itself under most circumstances.

10
Traditional Plains Indian Government
  • Only in times of war or disaster were wider
    economic and security arrangements unavoidable.
  • Government therefore functioned "at need" rather
    than as a permanent, coercive establishment.

11
Bureaucratic Dependence
  • But after relegation to reservations, government
    became both permanent and coercive.
  • "When we hear it said today that Indians do not
    believe in property or in private enterprise, we
    are still hearing the echoes of the struggle
    against Indian agrarian entrepreneurs in the
    1930sa struggle waged in the name of liberating
    landless Indians from poverty, but which in
    reality returned reservation economies to
    government dependence" (Barsh, 1987, p. 89).

12
Understanding the Political and Bureaucratic
Environment
  • Dominant Economic Theory of Government before
    1970s Government pursues the public interest
  • If markets fail, government can correct the
    problem
  • Government can replace markets (central planning,
    socialism)
  • Policies toward Indian reservations often have
    been experiments in socialism rather than
    capitalism.

13
Public Choice and the Theory of Government
Failure
  • Takes an economic approach to the analysis of
    government, pointing out that special interest
    problems can lead to government failure
  • Rejects the public interest theory of
    government
  • Public interest is a normative concept and each
    persons subjective values determine their
    beliefs about what the public interest is.

14
Property Rights as the Object of Interest Group
Demand
  • Define the objects of interest group demand, and
    the functions of government law as a) the
    assignment of property rights, and b) enforcement
    of each property rights assignment
  • Property rights convey the ability to benefit
    oneself or harm others and dictate the
    distribution of wealth
  • Changes in property rights reallocate, destroy,
    or create rents and therefore transfer wealth
  • Whenever an interest group is successful in
    altering the assignment of property rights, other
    individuals lose, so political competition is
    likely even if some groups are not seeking
    monetary or physically measurable wealth or rents

15
Interest Groups
  • May pursue obvious self-interests
  • May pursue what members believe is in the public
    interest
  • Bruce Yandle, Bootleggers and Baptists
  • Individuals and groups pursuing their
    self-interests often can take advantage of the
    efforts of groups pursuing what they see as the
    public interests
  • Relatively small groups with large per capita
    stakes tend to dominate, due to information and
    organizing costs

16
Costs of Organizing
  • Two relevant costs
  • the cost of arriving at an agreement, and
  • the cost of enforcing an agreement
  • Negotiation required to determine objectives and
    strategies
  • If everyone in a group (of any size) has
    interests in common, then they will act
    collectively to achieve them.

17
The Logic of Collective Action
  • Large groups will face relatively high costs when
    attempting to organize for collective action
    while small groups will face relatively low
    costs.
  • Each individual member has incentives to avoid
    paying a full share (free ride).
  • Small groups may be effective while large groups
    may not be because it is easier to negotiate in
    and then police an interest group that is small.

18
Special Interests
  • Government provides benefits for "special
    interests" who are able to influence the
    political process.
  • Government confers concentrated benefits to
    special interests, spreading the individual
    small costs across many consumers and taxpayers.
  • Individuals who have discretionary power in the
    political process (politicians, government
    employees) also pursue their own subjective
    values.

19
White Farmers as Special Interests
  • The Dawes Act (also called General Allotment
    Act), adopted by Congress in 1887, authorized the
    President of the United States to survey Indian
    tribal land and divide it into allotments for
    individual Indians.
  • The act also provided that the government would
    purchase Indian land "excess" to that needed for
    allotment and open it up for settlement by
    non-Indians.
  • Bureaucracy responsible for procedures.

20
Bureaucratic Preferences
  • Bureaucratic authorities can be viewed as firms
    producing a service or a set of services
    including enforcement of legislatively determined
    property rights assignments.
  • Exchange their services for a budget
  • Bureaucrats are utility maximizers with income
    and non-monetary perquisites (e.g., prestige,
    staff support, travel, leisure time or shirking,
    social and physical amenities, discretion to do
    the job) as arguments in utility functions.
  • Income and perquisites tend to be functions of
    both bureau output (i.e., the size of the bureau)
    and the discretionary budget

21
Constraints on Bureaucrats
  • Mangers of enforcement bureaus prefer stricter
    enforcement of whatever restrictions exist than
    the legislature wants, and also try to
    inefficiently enforce rights in the sense of
    spending a larger budget per unit of enforcement
    than is necessary, if they can appropriate part
    of the budgets allocated by the legislature for
    their own benefit.
  • If there were no constraints on legislators' time
    and resources, they would force politically
    efficient behavior, but constraints do exist.
  • Legislators and interest groups monitor bureaus
    and use other control devises but control is
    "imperfect"

22
Example
  • Lindsay (1976) recognizes that many bureaus
    produce numerous outputs, some of which are
    easily measurable and some of which are not.
  • Bureaucrat has incentives to produce the
    measurable outputs that correspond to the
    monitor's desires, while exploiting the
    uncertainty associated with unmeasurable outputs
    (e.g., to gain discretionary budget)
  • Veteran's Administration provides expected levels
    of easily measured outputs (hospital beds,
    patient days) but relatively low quality services
    for unmeasurable outputs
  • If all dimensions cannot be monitored, then some
    power to scrimp on these attributes rest with
    those in the bureau, who can use the savings to
    forward their own interests"

23
Eliminating Ethnic Communities
  • Carlson notes that "no student of property-rights
    literature will be surprised that the
    complicated and heavily supervised property right
    that emerged from allotment led to
    inefficiencies, corruption, and losses for both
    Indians and society."
  • One of the major costs of transferring land to
    non-Indians may have been the reduced sense of an
    ethnic community on reservations.
  • McChesney calls this an "ethnic externality,"
    meaning that outside customs and cultures made it
    harder to maintain tribal customs and culture.

24
How to Explain the Dawes Act?
  • According to the special interest theory of
    politics, laws are passed because they confer
    benefits upon interest groups that are
    influential in the political arena.
  • In this case, the General Allotment Act formed
    the proverbial "iron triangle" of politics in
    which white settlers got the land, politicians
    received votes, and bureaucrats increased their
    budgets.

25
(No Transcript)
26
(No Transcript)
27
Public versus Private Interest
  • The guardianship model of Indian policy explains
    the relationship between the federal government
    and Indians as an effort by the government to
    correct imperfections in the institutional
    structure on Indian reservations.
  • Many reformers saw allotment as the only way to
    "Americanize" the Indian.

28
Allotment (1887)
  • The dates when reservations were allotted varied
    considerably across Indian Country.
  • On some reservations, allotment ensued the first
    year after the Dawes Act, whereas on others
    allotment did not take place until after 1930.
  • Once allotted, the lands originally were to be
    held in trust by the federal government for 25
    years, at the end of which time the Indian was to
    receive full fee simple title to the land.

29
Leasing Allowed
  • During the period of trusteeship, the land was
    not to be sold, leased, or willed to another
    Indian or non-Indian.
  • But because many allotted lands were not coming
    into production, the act was amended in 1891 to
    permit leasing with the result that "leasing soon
    became more prevalent than working one's own plot
    on many reservations."
  • 112,000 acres out of 140,000 acres of allotted
    lands on the Omaha and Winnebago reservations
    were leased by 1898 (1984, p. 673).
  • The 1906 amendment to the General Allotment Act
    authorized the Secretary of Interior to issue fee
    patents immediately if any Indian was deemed
    "competent and capable of managing his or her
    affairs."

30
Decline in Indian Land
  • When fee simple title to allotted lands or
    surplus lands passed to individuals, the land was
    no longer considered "Indian Land"even if it was
    owned by an Indian.
  • The total amount of Indian land declined
    dramatically between 1871 and 1983 (see Table
    5.2) as fee simple patents were issued by the
    federal government.
  • Measured in terms of privatization, the General
    Allotment Act was incredibly effective measured
    in terms of Indian ownership, however, it was a
    disaster.
  • According to Washburn, "about 60 percent of this
    land passed out of Indian hands" (1971, p. 145).

31
(No Transcript)
32
Special Interest Theory of Politics
  • Given that so many acres were transferred from
    Indian to white hands under this act, a special
    interest theory of politics provides an
    alternative to the "guardianship model" of
    allotment.
  • According to this theory, non-Indian special
    interest groups would seek legislation that would
    enable these groups to capture the wealth of
    reservations through political processes.
  • With reservations being established at precisely
    the time when western land values were rising,
    whites who were excluded from settling these
    reservations had an incentive to find a mechanism
    to obtain access.

33
Demand for Legislation
  • The General Allotment Act allowed whites to
    purchase land from allottees or tribes or to
    homestead the surplus.
  • As a result, non-Indians ended up on the
    receiving end of "one of the largest real estate
    transfers in history."
  • If the white settlers were the demanders of this
    legislation, the politicians and bureaucrats were
    the suppliers.

34
Policies for Votes
  • Given that Indians constituted a small portion of
    the population and that many Indians could not or
    did not vote anyway, congressional committees
    represented the interests of non-Indian
    constituents, and policy was catered to
    constituents.
  • If whites wanted access to Indian lands, they
    would expect their representatives to deliver the
    policies that would satisfy their demands for
    access.
  • The General Allotment Act did this.

35
Bureaucratic Influence
  • If land-hungry settlers were the main
    beneficiaries of allotment policy, why weren't
    Indians granted outright title to the allotments
    so that white intrusion could occur faster?
  • Or why wasn't all reservation land declared
    surplus and opened to homesteading?
  • The answer centers around the desire of the
    bureaucracy to increase its budget.

36
Bureaucrats as Policy Advocates
  • Bureaucrats are not only a government employee.
  • They are at the same time voters and as such
    employers of politicians.
  • Their pecuniary interests as employees probably
    dominate their interests as employers, as they
    get much more from the public funds than they
    contributes to them
  • This double relationship becomes more important
    as the people on the government's payroll
    increase.
  • Bureaucrat as voter is more eager to get a raise
    than to keep the budget balanced.
  • Therefore, bureaucrats are in a position to be
    "policy advocates" rather than simply policy
    implementers

37
Bureaucratic Pursuit of Policy Changes
  • Bureaucratic institutional process tends to be
    dominated by individual bureaucrats pursuing
    their subjective goals by selectively seeking and
    implementing policy innovations.
  • Part of the general struggle for budgets, as well
    as competition for positions and promotions
  • Propagate" their own policy agendas and have a
    relative advantage in interest group competition
  • Already organized, well informed about a narrowly
    focused political issues, generally can
    appropriate a portion of their discretionary
    budgets to cover some or all of their lobbying
    costs, and they have ready access to those who
    pass laws and set budgets

38
Bureaucrats Create Uncertainty
  • Bureaucrats' power and discretion depend on the
    degree of uncertainty, and they often can
    increase uncertainty through "selective
    distortion
  • Oversight sponsor faces the duel problem of
    determining both what the bureaus output should
    be from a political perspective, and how it
    should be produced, with the potential for
    bureaucrats misleading them on both counts.
  • Incentives to "educate" sponsors, by selectively
    informing them of the strength and wishes of
    other interest groups.
  • Therefore, interest groups press their demands to
    bureaucracies as well as (or instead of) to
    legislatures.

39
Information and Misinformation
  • Bureaucrats have incentives to "educate"
    potential interest group allies and to
    "propagate" their agenda through "public
    information" or misinformation campaigns.
  • Strategies employed by bureaucrats include
  • "(i) Alterations in the flows of in information
    or commands as these move through or across the
    hierarchical levels of the organization
  • (ii) Variations in the quality or quantity of
    information leaked to the media, to other bureaus
    in the organization, to special interest groups,
    and/or to opposition parties and rival suppliers
    and
  • (iii) Changes in the speed of implementation of
    policies as these are put into effect" (Breton
    and Wintrobe 1982)

40
Bureaucratic Environment
  • Strategies and selective behavior in general are
    possible because of the way bureaucratic
    organizations and hierarchies work
  • Monitoring by superiors and sponsors is costly
    and the measurement of bureaucratic performance
    is generally difficult or impossible
  • Such strategies can increase monitoring costs and
    make measurement of performance even more
    difficult
  • Individuals who depend on a particular
    bureaucratic process for their livelihood have
    strong incentives to maintain it and prevent the
    implementation of competitive alternatives.

41
Bureaucracys Expanding Role
  • By amending the Dawes Act in 1891 to allow for
    leasing allotments that had not been released
    from trusteeship, Congress allowed whites access
    to the lands while preserving an important role
    for the bureaucracy.
  • This gave Indian agents even more power, because
    it was up to them to determine and enforce the
    terms of leases.
  • "Leases came to be granted more and more freely,
    and by the turn of the century, the leasing of
    allotments was relatively common." (Carlson,
    1981, p. 37).

42
Hypotheses
  • From the special interest theory of allotment
    three hypotheses follow
  • 1. Congressional committee decisions will reflect
    the demands of constituents, and policies will
    change as these demands change.
  • 2. Allotment would occur first in those areas
    where whites placed a higher value on the land
    held by Indians.
  • 3. As the allotment process transferred millions
    of acres out of BIA control, the bureaucracy
    would have lost nearly all of its power had it
    not halted the process by retaining trust
    authority under the 1934 Indian Reorganization
    Act.

43
Hypothesis 1
  • Throughout the history of government policy
    regarding Indian property rights, those rights
    often have been ambiguous, leaving the assignment
    of those rights to bureaucratic discretion.
  • With Indian property rights not clearly
    specified, Congress and its agenciessuch as the
    Bureau of Indian Affairshave been in a position
    to redistribute the sticks in the bundle of
    rights to special interest constituencies.

44
Cherokee Outlet
  • By not specifying exactly what rights the
    Cherokees had to their land in Oklahoma, Congress
    provided itself an opportunity to respond to
    changing constituent demands.

45
Hypothesis 1 (contd)
  • The Cherokees, ranchers who grazed cattle in the
    outlet (CSLA), and the Boomers (people who wanted
    to farm the Outlet) competed for the right to use
    the Outlet.
  • Ultimately the Boomers won the battle as Congress
    passed an appropriation bill in 1889 authorizing
    payment of 1.25 per acre to the Cherokees, and
    in October 1889 the secretary of the interior
    ordered the CSLA to remove its cattle from the
    Outlet.

46
Hypothesis 1 (contd)
  • The explanation for the Boomer victory is found
    in the relationship between constituents and
    their congressional representatives.
  • Though the ranchers were well organized, the
    Boomers were growing in numbers and by 1870
    outnumbered cattlemen in every state bordering
    the Outlet.
  • The combination of larger numbers and higher land
    prices provided the necessary demand stimulus for
    changing the property rights to the Outlet.

47
Hypothesis 2
  • Just as the Boomers brought pressure to open the
    Cherokee Outlet for settlement, white farmers saw
    opportunity on Indian lands all over the West.
  • Throughout the 19th century, government land
    policy had made the public domain available at
    low prices to those willing to endure the
    hardships of frontier life.
  • With the Homestead Act beginning in the 1860s,
    people could obtain title to land by paying a
    small fee, generally 1.25 per acre, residing on
    the land for five years, and making improvements
    on the land.
  • With rising land values in the West, settlers had
    an interest in obtaining access to reservation
    lands.

48
Dawes Act (1887)
  • The passage of the Dawes Act in 1887 provided the
    whites access to many, though not all,
    reservations.
  • Whether and when allotment began varied across
    reservations, but once the process began,
    non-Indians had access to Indian land.
  • Lands released from trusteeship could be bought
    and sold with clear title, and even prior to
    release they could be leased as a result of
    congressional action in 1891.
  • Moreover, if there were surplus lands after
    allotment, they were opened to homesteading by
    anyone.

49
Hypothesis 2 (contd)
  • Since survey and administrative expenses made it
    costly for the Office of Indian Affairs to allot
    a reservation, those areas in highest demand by
    non-Indians should receive first attention.
  • Carlson finds that, as with the Cherokee Outlet,
    the data support the theory that Indian policy
    was heavily dominated by non-Indian interest
    groups.

50
Carlsons Test
  • The demand theory of allotment helps explain when
    allotment occurred.
  • "The more desirable a reservation was to
    outsiders, the more pressure they would have
    placed on the Office of Indian Affairs and the
    more likely that it would have been allotted
    sooner.

51
Carlsons Findings
  • Carlson estimated the date of allotment as a
    function of a number of variables that would
    reflect a larger demand for allotment.
  • These variables included rainfall, percent of
    improved land in the state in which the
    reservation is located, and population density of
    the state in which the reservation is located.
  • As with the Cherokee Outlet, these data support
    the theory that Indian policy was heavily
    dominated by non-Indian interest groups.

52
Hypothesis 3
  • Expectations were that allotment would lead to
    the end of the Indian bureaucracy.
  • Subsequent growth of the BIA , however, suggests
    that the ringing of the death toll was premature.
  • Rather than decline, the bureau continued to grow
    in both employment and budget, and other agencies
    responsible for education, housing, and welfare
    have increasingly devoted attention to the
    "Indian problem."

53
Hypothesis 3 (contd)
  • Evidence of the BIA's recognition that it might
    be working itself out of a job comes from the
    words of the Commissioner of Indian Affairs in
    1906 "The grand total of the nation's wards will
    be diminished and at a growing ratio."
  • But "instead of withering away according to the
    blueprint, the Indian Office vastly increased its
    involvement it became a sort of real estate
    agent, handling a multitude of land transactions
    for individual Indians."

54
BIA Expands its Mission
  • The BIA found its raison d'etre with the passage
    of the Indian Reorganization Act in 1934.
  • In addition to establishing tribal governments,
    the act ended the allotment process and froze
    most allotments for which fee patents had not
    been issued into perpetual trusteeship.
  • McChesney notes that
  • In its initial phases, allotment would serve
    bureaucrats' interest in greater budgets because
    it necessitated a growing Indian Office to
    administer the Dawes Act. . . . Ending allotments
    and freezing ownership for allottees still under
    federal trusteeship guaranteed that bureaucratic
    control would continue

55
A New Mission
  • According to McChesney
  • Every change in the sequence of allotment events
    from 1887 to 1934 led to an increase in the
    involvement of the federal government in Indian
    affairs, and each change can be explained by its
    ability to generate more work for the Indian
    bureaucracy, (p. 127)

56
Bureaucracies Fail but Survive by Changing
  • Bureaucracies inevitably fail for reasons
    suggested above (e.g., individuals exploit
    uncontrolled margins)
  • In part, the failures are met by concealed
    shifts in the objectives for the organization...
    if one examines the original arguments for
    establishment of almost any government bureau and
    compares these arguments with those that may be
    currently offered for the retention of the
    bureau, one is likely to find that a considerable
    shift has occurred in the specification of the
    objectives that the bureau is supposed to attain.
    The governmental bureau becomes a permanent
    fixture, with the objective continually changing.
    Over time the vested interests of the bureaucrats
    themselves become more and more important in
    justifying the organization."

57
Bureaucratic Self-Preservation
  • The budget evidence mustered by McChesney is
    convincing.
  • Not only did BIA budgets grow but that growth was
    significantly increased by both the number of
    allotments and the acreage allotted.
  • But the rate of budget increase attributable to
    allotments declined over time, giving the BIA an
    incentive to find an alternative policy that
    would sustain bureaucratic growth.
  • The Indian Reorganization Act, which began during
    the New Deal, provided the policy change that has
    driven the agency even to the present.

58
Conclusion
  • There are, of course, arguments that the
    allotment experiment was a failure because it
    transferred so much land to whites, but there is
    no systematic evidence to test this proposition.
  • Certainly vast amounts of land were transferred
    to whites, but by itself this is not prima facie
    evidence that Indians were left worse off.
  • There is one conclusion, however, that is clear
    from the allotment episode rather than promoting
    self-reliance and self-determination for today's
    Indians, late 19th and early 20th century policy
    left reservation Indians entangled in a
    bureaucratic quagmire where they continue to be
    wards of the state.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com