Title: Coherent Measures of Risk
1Coherent Measures of Risk
- David Heath
- Carnegie Mellon University
- Joint work with Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen,
Jean-Marc Eber research partially funded by
Société Generale
2Measuring Risk
- Purpose
- Manage and control risk
- Make good risk/return tradeoff
- Risk adjust traders profits
- To help with
- Regulation of traders and banks
- Portfolio selection
- Motivating traders to reduce risk
3How should a risk measure behave?
- Should provide a basis for setting capital
requirements - Should be reasonable
- Encourage diversification
- Should respect more is better
- Should be useable as a management tool
- Should be compatible with allocation of risk
limits to desks - Should provide sensible way to risk-adjust
gains of different investment strategies (desks)
4The basic model
- For now, think only of market risk
- For now, assume liquid markets
- A state of the market w is then a set of prices
for all securities. (i.e., a copy of WSJ) - For a given portfolio p and a given state w, set
Xp(w) market value of p in state w. - A risk measure r assigns a number r(X) to each
such (random variable) X.
5More generally ...
- Notice r maps Xs (not ps) into numbers.
- More complexity can be introduced through X
- X should give the value of the firm if required
to liquidate at the end of period, for every
possible state of the world - State w can specify amount of liquidity
- Can consider active management over period
- w must describe evolution of markets over period
- instead of portfolio p, must consider strategy
(e.g., rebalance each day using futures to stay
hedged)
6Lets focus on r
- Want r to provide capital requirements.
- Suppose firm is required to allocate additional
capital - what do they do with it - Riskless investment (which, and how riskless)?
- Risky investment?
- We assume some particular instrument is
specified. Its price today is 1, and at end is
r0(w). (Might be pdb, money market, SP) - r(X) tells the number of shares of this security
which must be added to the portfolio to make it
safe enough.
7Axioms for coherent r
- Units
- r(Xar0) r(X) - a (for all a)
- Diversification
- r((XY)/2) (r(X)r(Y))/2
- More is better
- If X Y then r(Y) r(X)
- Scale invariance
- r(aX) a r(X) (for all a ³ 0)
8An aside ...
- In the presence of the linearity axiom, the
diversification axiom can be written - r(XY) r(X) r(Y)
- This means that a risk limit can be allocated
to desks - If the inequality failed for a firm desiring to
hold XY, firm could reduce capital requirement
by setting up two subsidiaries, one to hold X and
the other Y.
9Do any such r exist?
- Do we want one? (Maybe not!)
- There are many such rs
- Take any set A of outcomes
- Set rA(X) - infX(w)/r0(w) wÎA
- Think of A as set of scenarios r gives worst
case - Take any set of probabilities P
- Set rp(X) - infEP(X/r0) PÎP
- Think of each P as a generalized scenario
10Are there any more?
- Theorem If W is a finite set, then every
coherent risk measure can be obtained from
generalized scenarios. - So specifying a coherent risk measure is the
same as specifying a set of generalized scenarios.
11How can (or does) one pick generalized scenarios?
- SPAN uses generalized scenarios
- To set margin on a portfolio consisting of shares
of some futures contract and options on that
contract, consider prices (scenarios) by - Let the futures price change by -3/3, -2/3, -1/3,
0, 1/3, 2/3, 3/3 of some range, and vols either
move up or move down. (These are scenarios.) - Let the futures go up or down by an extreme
move, vols stay the same. Need cover only 35 of
the loss. (These are generalized )
12Another method
- Let each desk generate relevant scenarios for
instruments it trades pass these to firms risk
manager - Risk manager takes all combinations of these
scenarios and may add some more - Resulting set of scenarios is given back to each
desk, which must value its portfolio for each - Results are combined by firm risk manager
13What about VaR?
- VaR specifies a risk measure rVaR
- rVaR is computed for an X as follows For a
given probability P (the best guess at the true
(physical or martingale?) probability) - Compute the .01 quantile of the distribution of X
under P - The negative of this quantile rVaR(X)
- (implicitly assumes r0 1.)
14VaR is not coherent!
- VaR satisfies all axioms except diversification
(and it uses r0 1). - This means VaR limits cant be allocated to
desks each desk might satisfy limit but total
portfolio might not. - Firms avoid VaR restrictions by setting up
subsidiaries
15VaR says dont diversify!
- Consider a CCC bond. Suppose
- Probability of default over a week is .005
- Value after default is 0
- Yield spread is .26/yr or .005/week
- Consider the portfolio
- Borrow 300,000 at risk-free rate
- Purchase 300,000 of this bond
- Value at end if no default is 1500
- Probability of default is .005, so VaR says OK!
- In fact, can do this to any scale!
16If you diversify
- If there are 3 independent bonds like this
- Consider borrowing 300,000 and purchasing
100,000 of each bond - Probability distribution of worth at end
- (Lets pretend interest rate
0) - Probability Value
- 0.985075 1500
- 0.01485 -99000 VaR requires
99000 - 7.46E-05 -199500
- 1.25E-07 -300000
17Even scarier
- Most firms want to get the highest return per
unit of risk. - If they use VaR to measure risk, theyll be led
to pile up the losses on a small set of
scenarios (a set with probability less than .01) - If they use black box approach to reducing VaR
theyll do the same, probably without realizing
it!
18Does anything like VaR work?
- Suppose we have chosen a P which wed use to
compute VaR - Suppose X has a continuous distribution (under P)
- Then set r(X) -EP(X X -VaR(X))
- This r is coherent! (requires a proof)
- Its the smallest coherent r which depends only
on the P-distribution of Xs and which is bigger
than VaR.
19More about this VaR-like r
- To compute a 1 VaR by simulation, one might
generate 10,000 random scenarios (using P) and
use -the 100th worst one. - The corresponding estimate of our r would be the
negative of the average of the 100 worst ones - If X is normally distributed, this r(X) is very
close to VaR - This may be a good first step toward coherence
20Whats next?
- What are the consequences of trying to maximize
return per unit of risk when using a coherent
risk measure? - We think that something like that does make sense
- Could a bank perform well if each desk used such
a measure? - We think so.
21Conclusions (to part 1 of talk)
- Good risk management requires the use of coherent
risk measures - VaR is not a coherent risk measure
- Can induce firms to arrange portfolio so that
when the fail, they fail big - Discourages diversification
- There is a substitute for VaR which is more
conservative than VaR, is about as easy to
compute, and is coherent
22Ongoing research (results tentative!!)
- Can coherent risk measures be used for
- Firm-wide risk management?
- In portfolio selection?
- What criteria make one coherent risk measure (or
one set of generalized scenarios) better than
another? - Can such measures help with
- Decentralized portfolio optimization?
- Risk adjusting trading profits?
23Maxing expected return per unit risk
- Using VaR, problem is
- Maximize E(X)
- subject to VaR(X) K
- Problem is (usually) unbounded
- It is if theres any X with E(X)gt0 and
VaR(X) 0 (like being short a far out-of-
the-money put) - VaR constraint is satisfied for arbitrarily large
position size!
24With a coherent risk measure
- Well see that
- Firms can achieve economically optimal
portfolios - Decision problem can be allocated to desks
- Desks can each have their own PDesk
- If these arent too inconsistent, still works!
- But first -- in addition to regulators we need
the firms owners
25Meeting goals of shareholders
- So far, risk measures were for regulation
- Shareholders have a different point of view
- Solvency isnt enough
- Dont want too much risk of loss of investment
- Shareholders may have different risk preferences
than regulators - Firm must respect both regulators and
shareholders demands
26A shareholders risk measure
- Require firm to count shareholders investment as
liability - This desired shareholder value may be
- Fixed
- Some index
- In general, some random variable, say T (target)
- Risk is the risk of missing target
- Apply coherent risk measure to X-T.
- Shareholders have risk measure rSH
27The optimization problem
- Let rReg denote the regulators risk measure
- Let P be some given probability measure
- Let T be the investors target
- Let rSH be the shareholders risk measure
- Problem Choose available X to maximize EP(X)
subject to rReg(X) 0 and
rSH(X-T) 0.
28In liquid markets Linear Program
- In liquid markets the initial price of X, p0(X)
is a linear function of X. - Traded Xs form a linear space
- Available Xs satisfy p0(X) K (capital)
- Objective function (EP(X)) is linear in X
- Constraints, written properly, are linear
- rReg(X) 0 is same as EQ(X) ³ 0 for all Q Î QReg
- rSH(X-T) 0 is same as EQ(X) ³ EQ(T) for all Q Î
QSH
29Is the resulting portfolio optimal?
- Can firm get to shareholders optimal X?
- Suppose
- Shareholders (or managers) have a utility
function u, strictly increasing - Desired portfolio is solution X to
- Maximize EP(u(X)) over all available X satisfying
regulators constraints - Suppose such an X exists
- Can managers specify T and rSH so that X is the
solution to the above LP?
30Forcing optimality
- Theorem
- Let T X and QSH set of all probability
measures. Then the only feasible solution to the
LP is X. - Proof If X is feasible, then shareholder
constraints require X ³ T ( X). But if any
available X ³ X were actually larger (on a set
with positive P-measure), EP(u(X)) would be
bigger than EP(u(X)), so X wouldnt have
maximized expected utility
31If the firm has trading desks
- Let X1, X2, , XD the spaces of random terminal
worths available to desks 1, 2, D - Then random variables available to firm are
elements of X X1 X2 XD . - Suppose target T is allocated arbitrarily to
desks so that T T1 T2 TD. - Suppose initial capital is arbitrarily allocated
to desks K K1 KD
32- and Regulators risk is assigned (for each
regulator probability Q Î QReg) to desks rQ,1,
rQ,2, , rQ,D summing to 0.
33Let desk d try to solve
- Choose Xd Î Xd to maximize EP(Xd) subject to
- p0(Xd) Kd
- EQ(Xd) ³ EQ(Td) for every Q Î QSH
- EQ(Xd) ³ rQ,d for every Q Î QReg
34Clearly ...
- X1 X2 XD is feasible for the firms
problem, so EP(X1XD) is EP(X). - i.e., desks cant get better total solution than
firm could get - Since X can be decomposed as X1 X2 XD
where Xd Î Xd, with appropriate splitting of
resources as above desks will achieve optimal
portfolio for the firm
35How can firm do this allocation?
- Set up an internal market for perturbations of
all of the arbitrary allocations. Desks can
trade such perturbations i.e., can agree that
one desk will lower the rhs of one of its
constraints and the other will increase its. But
this agreement has a price (to be set internally
by this market). (Value of each desks objective
function is lowered by the amount of its payments
in this internal market.)
36Market equilibrium
- The only equilibrium for this market produces the
optimal portfolio for the firm. - (Look at the firms dual problem this tells the
equilibrium internal prices associated with each
constraint.)
37What if each desk has its own Pd?
- If there is some P such that EPd(X) EP(X) for
all X Î Xd then any market equilibrium solves the
firms LP for this measure P. - If there isnt then there is internal arbitrage
and no market equilibrium exists.