Title: Chapter 12 Labour Market Applications
1Chapter 12Labour Market Applications
2Minimum Wage Legislation
- The real question regarding minimum wage
legislations is, do they help the working poor? - Does it achieve a desired redistribution of
income? - Are workers in the industry better-off?
- Whose income falls to make up for the rise in
minimum wage income? - Is inefficiency an invariable side effect?
3Figure 12.1 Minimum-wage legislation in a
competitive labour market
4Minimum Wage in a Competitive Labour Market
- In a competitive market, inefficiency is a
necessary by-product of an effective minimum wage
law. - As labour services are no longer put to their
most productive uses, either unemployment or
underemployment will signal that inefficiency. - Underemployed workers in Figure 12.1 are those
who have a marginal product of 12 in this
industry, but choose to work in a less productive
industry rather than face the chance of
unemployment.
5Monopsonistic Labour Markets
- A monopsonistic labour market has a single buyer
of labour. - The implications of minimum-wage legislation are
very different compared to a competitive market. - Figures 12.2 and 12.3 illustrate why this is the
case.
6Figure 12.2 Minimum wage and a monopsonists
marginal factor cost
7From Figure 12.2
- Once a minimum wage is brought into a monopsony,
the marginal factor cost (MFC) will change. - The monopsonists pre-legislation MFC is the line
segment DBC. - The post-legislation MFC is now two lines, wA
and BC.
8From Figure 12.2
- If the monopsonist hires an amount of labour less
than z, its MFC is w. - If it hires beyond that point, its MFC is segment
BC of its original MFC function because it can
hire additional workers only at a wage rate
higher than w.
9Figure 12.3 Minimum wage and monopsony
10From Figure 12.3
- Does a minimum wage increase workers incomes?
- Yes. As long as the wage is not higher than w,
some workers are better off and none worse off.
Why? - - At w or below, it has no effect.
- - At above w but below w, workers hired
before the introduction of the minimum wage
will be paid more and new workers will be hired
at the new (minimum) wage. - - If the rate is w, no new workers are hired,
but existing workers will be paid more.
11Minimum Wage Legislation
- The attractiveness of minimum wage legislation
depends upon whether labour markets are
competitive or monopsonistic. - Empirical evidence suggests that labour markets
covered by minimum wage laws are competitive, and
the laws are problematic.
12Minimum Wage Legislation
- Workers who remain employed are better off. It is
not clear at whose expense the gain is made (we
do not know who pays). - By creating unemployment and underemployment, the
legislation will hurt some people it was intended
to help.
13Union Wage Rates
- Although analyzing the economic consequences of
unionization objectively is not easy, we can move
in that direction by adapting our minimum-wage
analysis to apply to union wages rates. - In this analysis, the union wage is treated like
a wage floor - setting a minimum wage paid in a
unionized industry.
14Figure 12.4 A wage floor in the two-sector model
of the labour market
15From Figure 12.4
- Imposing the wage floor means that some workers
are reallocated from sector 1 to sector 2 and as
a result, the wage rate in sector 2 falls. - Because 6 is less than the competitive wage of
9, workers are not allocated to their most
productive jobs. - The wage floor yields an equilibrium with
underemployment.
16From Figure 12.4
- Assume there are unionized and non-unionized
sectors and that the unionized sector is
characterized by a shape up (all members turn
up each day and a union official picks the
members who work that day). - Workers are free to seek work in either sector.
The number of workers looking for jobs in the
union shape up is z1 and those looking in the
non-unionized sector is z2.
17From Figure 12.4
- 20 jobs at the union wage of 12 are shared by
all union members. - Assuming the jobs are shared equally, the
proportion of time that any union member will be
employed is 20/z1 (jobs/union members). - The expected wage is the union wage (12) times
20/z1 or 240/z1.
18Figure 12.5 Wage floors and search unemployment
in a two-sector model
19From Figure 12.5
- Figure 12.5 is different from 12.4 in that the
expected wage rate is plotted in quadrant I. - Notice that the expected wage relationship passes
point G in quadrant I because when 20 union
workers look for jobs in the shape up each is
employed full time at the union wage of 12 per
hour.
20From Figure 12.5
- Suppose the workers continue to join the union
sector until the expected wage in the union
sector equals that on the non-union sector. - Equilibrium allocation is at point C in quadrant
III, with a wage of 8.
21From Figure 12.5
- At equilibrium point C
- 30 unionized workers are chasing 20 union jobs
paying 12. - As unionized workers split available work
equally, the expected wage is 240/30 8.
22From Figure 12.5
- At equilibrium point C
- 70 workers are employed in sector 2
- Unemployment equals u in quadrant I, (10 full
time workers). - Note that in equilibrium in Figure 12.4 (point B
in Figure 12.5), 80 non-union workers are
employed in sector 2.
23From Figure 12.5
- It is necessary that the equilibrium wage in
sector two of the underemployment model is lower
than that in the unemployment model. Why? - Because in the unemployment model, some non-union
workers leave sector 2 to chase jobs in sector 1. - As a result, the smaller number of non-union
workers remaining in sector 2 will earn a higher
wage.
24From Figure 12.5
- Two sources of inefficiency arise in this model
- There is unemployment equal to u in quadrant I.
- The allocation of workers who are employed is
inefficient because the wage floor exceeds the
equilibrium wage.
25Income Maintenance
- What institution is best for transferring income
to the poorer members of society? - Efficient transfer mechanism
- Topping-up mechanism
- Negative income tax
26Figure 12.6 An efficient income-transfer mechanism
27The Efficient Transfer Mechanism
- Although the lump-sum mechanism is efficient, it
is not practical. - There is no systematic way of choosing a target
indifference curve or identifying individual
preferences and budgets to pinpoint recipients. - As a result, policies are formulated in terms of
income-maintenance mechanisms rather than
utility-maintenance mechanisms.
28Income-Maintenance Programs
- Income-maintenance programs have the objective of
raising the income of anyone below a targeted
level of income, up to that level. - In practical income-maintenance schemes, the
amount of the income transfer is conditional upon
the amount of the recipients earned income.
29Topping Up and Welfare
- The essential feature of many welfare programs is
a topping-up mechanism, where the subsidy is just
large enough to put the recipient at the mandated
income level. - The result is that potential recipients can
affect the amount of income transferred to them
by choosing how much income they earn.
30Topping Up and Welfare
- If the potential recipient earns as much or more
than the targeted income level (S), he/she will
not get any subsidy. - If he/she earns an income below S, the amount of
the subsidy will be just enough to raise total
income to S. - This topping-up mechanism translates into the
kinked budget line in Figure 12.7.
31Topping Up and Welfare
- This topping-up mechanism translates into the
kinked budget line in Figure 12.7, which leads to
inefficiency. - The inefficiency occurs because the recipients
MRS at E, is less than the wage rate.
32Figure 12.7 An inefficient income-transfer
mechanism
33The Negative Income Tax
- The negative income tax (NIT) combines the
elements of the efficient lump-sum transfer and
the topping-up mechanism. - Though not problem-free, this combined scheme
redistributes income to poorer members of society
without the gross inefficiency and the perverse
lack of work incentives associated with the
welfare system.
34Figure 12.8 A negative income tax
35From Figure 12.8
- This version of the NIT combines an unconditional
income transfer for everyone (S) and a
proportionate (yet moderate) income tax (t) on
earned income. - Everyone receives the subsidy (S), pays twh in
taxes, keeps (1-t)wh from his/her earned income,
and receives net income equal to - x2 S (1-t)wh
36From Figure 12.8
- At point E in Figure 12.8, the budget line is
tangent to the indifference curve and the person
is indifferent between the NIT and the topping-up
mechanism. - This person works h hours and earns income equal
to wh.
37From Figure 12.8
- Point E is not an efficient equilibrium because
the MRS is less than w. - The NIT offsets some of the inefficiencies
associated with the topping-up mechanism and
avoids the disincentive to work. - It also makes smaller demand on the public purse
(DE for the NIT versus S for the topping-up
mechanism).
38The Market for Superstars
- Figure 12.9 shows two separate labour markets.
There is a market demand and supply curve for
talent levels of t0.25 and the same for talent
levels of t0.35. - Consumers are willing to pay more for talented
singers and we assume they can produce more CDs.
39Figure 12.9 Labour markets with different levels
of talent
40The market for Superstars
- A superstar market is characterized by a good or
service that has a poor substitutability between
quantity and quality. - Also a small number of individuals are able to
supply the entire market. - More talented labour produces more CDs and gets a
higher wage.