State Preference Theory - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

State Preference Theory

Description:

Title: No Slide Title Author: GSOM LAB 2 Last modified by: School of Business Created Date: 7/25/1996 10:54:52 AM Document presentation format: On-screen Show – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:50
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 20
Provided by: GSO66
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: State Preference Theory


1
State Preference Theory
  • Advanced economies facilitate individuals
    savings/consumption decisions and firms
    investing/financing decisions through securities
    trading.
  • In equilibrium, securities supply equals demand
    and firms maximize profits while consumers
    maximize expected utility.
  • This and the next two lectures consider issues
    necessary to resolve the problem of how
    individuals select among risky securities to
    maximize their expected utility over time.
  • Todays Topic How are security prices determined
    when they offer given payoffs in particular
    states of the world, but where the state that
    will be realized at a future point in time is
    uncertain?
  • What is a security? A vector of payoffs
    associated with different states of the world at
    some future date.
  • The investors portfolio can then be
    characterized as a matrix of possible payoffs on
    his securities.

2
State Specific Securities
  • 1. Simple Model
  • Two states of nature, 1 and 2, with associated
  • probabilities ?1 and ?2 .
  • Assume that the states are exclusive and
    exhaustive so that the probabilities sum to 1.
    Here this means that ?2 (1 - ?1).
  • Pure state security 1 (2) pays off 1 if state 1
    (2) is realized and nothing otherwise. If both
    securities exist then the securities market is
    said to be complete.
  • Assume investors are able to associate payoffs
    with states and that utility is not a direct
    function of the realized state but depends only
    on how much wealth they receive each state.
  • 2. Under these conditions, investors can buy pure
    securities to obtain their desired future wealth
    given the constraint defined by their current
    wealth and the prices of the pure securities p1
    and p2. The prices of the pure securities will
    reflect their supply from firms and their
    demand from investors/consumers.

3
A Complete Capital Market of Complex Securities
1. Markets consist of many complex securities
rather than pure securities. 2. Complex
securities are just linear combinations of the
pure securities. For example, a security paying
3 in state 1 and 2 in state 2 is equivalent to
a portfolio of 3 shares of pure security 1, and
2 shares of pure security 2. 3. When there are S
states, and there are at least S complex
securities that have linearly independent
payoffs, then the complex securities market is
complete. That is, the market can operate as if
there are S pure securities. In a complete
market, all risk is insurable. Example
Suppose there are three states and three
securities have the following payoff vectors XS
x1, x2, x3. Assume you can buy or sell
fractions of a share. Is this market complete?
X1 6, 6, 2, X23, 0, 0, X3 0, 3, 1.
Hint Combine the vectors into a matrix and see
if the matrix rank is 3. Alternatively, see if
the determinant is nonzero.
4
4. Options on complex securities allow an
incomplete market to be completed (see Ross
1976). If a state can be described by some price
for the complex security, then we can write
options on the security with a given strike price
to synthetically create a pure security that pays
off only in that state. 5. Long-lived securities
represent portfolios on pure securities that
allow us to have effectively complete markets
with a relatively small number of securities.
With many time periods and many states in each
time period, the number of pure securities needed
to complete a market seems very large. But in
fact, if there are enough long-lived complex
securities to cover the full range of states in
any period, then we may get by with a much
smaller number of securities. Since uncertainty
(the state) is revealed one period at a time, if
we know how the state revealed this period
affects all future period payoffs, then we can
use a relatively small number of long-lived
securities to effectively complete the market
period-by-period. We buy some long-lived
securities, not just because the payoff they
offer next period suits our needs, but also
because their payoffs for many future periods
suit our expected future needs as well.
5
  • Example of how to find pure securities prices
    given a complete market and securities payoffs.
  • ps prices of pure securities
  • Pj prices of complex securities
  • ?s state probabilities
  • Qs number of pure securities
  • 2. Consider two complex securities with the
    following payoffs in two states of the world X1
    10, 20, X230, 10. The price of the two
    securities is P1 8 and P2 9. We can find the
    pure securities prices as
  • P1 8 10p1 20 p2
  • P2 9 30p1 10p2
  • Solving two equations in two unknowns gives
  • p1 .20 and p2 .30.
  • We pay 20 cents today for a security that pays
    off 1 if state 1 occurs in the future and 30
    cents today for a security that pays off 1 if
    state 2 occurs in the future.

6
3. Cramers rule can be used to solve a system of
equations. P1 8 10p1 20 p2 P2 9 30p1
10p2 We can get the pi as the ratio of
determinants, pi Ai/A where A is the
matrix of coefficients on the pi in the system
and Ai is the same matrix with the ith column
replaced by the vector of complex securities
prices.
7
Law of One Price
  • Equilibrium in the securities market means that
    supply equals demand for all securities.
  • Equilibrium implies that securities with the same
    payoffs carry the same price. If they did not
    have the same price, supply would not equal
    demand individuals would sell the high-priced
    one and buy the low-priced one and earn a risk
    free return on the difference between the prices.
  • For a complete market, we can construct a
    risk-free security by buying one of each of the
    pure securities, which guarantees a 1 payoff.
    For the risk-free return r, in the previous
    example we have
  • p1 p2 .20 .30 .50 1/(1 r) gt r 1
    100
  • The risk-free rate reflects the time value of
    money and productivity of capital.

8
  • Other securities reflect time value and risk and
    offer a risk-premium, i.e., a larger rate of
    return.
  • Assuming homogeneous expectations for ?s, (all
    investors use the same state probabilities in
    their maximization problem), and that the price
    of an expected 1 payoff contingent on state S
    occurring is ?s, then
  • 1 E(Rs) ps1 (1 - ps)0/ps ps/ps
  • so that
  • ps ?s ?s ?s
  • Where E(Rs) is the expected return for a dollar
    payoff in state s. When investors highly value a
    dollar payoff in a particular state, they will
    accept a smaller return and pay a higher price
    (?s) today for it.
  • Question Why would investors value a dollar in
    state 1 more than a dollar in state 2? Doesnt
    the difference in probability of the two states
    occurring already account for this?

9
Diversifiable versus Undiversifiable Risk
  • The variation in aggregate wealth is
    undiversifiable. Because total wealth will be
    lower during recession and higher during
    expansion, someone must bear the risk of
    realizing a low return (low wealth) during a
    recession.
  • Those that accept the risk do so by purchasing
    securities that pay unusually low returns in
    recessions and unusually high returns in
    expansions positive payoff covariance with
    aggregate wealth (market portfolio of
    securities). Their reward for doing this is that
    the average returns for their securities over the
    full cycle of recession and expansion is larger
    than that of others.
  • If states 1 and 2 offer the same aggregate wealth
    (I.e., same security payout) and you hold more
    shares of pure security 1 than 2, you are taking
    on diversifiable risk.
  • If state 1 occurs, you get a larger piece of
    total wealth but if state 2 occurs you get a
    smaller piece. Had you simply diversified and
    held the same number of shares of each, you would
    have received the same wealth in each state. Your
    expected wealth is the same but you have
    introduced variance in the outcome.
  • Risk aversion implies that you should not accept
    additional variance in your wealth unless you are
    offered a larger expected wealth. But others in
    the securities market will not offer a larger
    return to you because it is costless for them to
    simply diversify to eliminate their risk. They do
    not need you to bear it for them.

10
Decomposition of Pure Securities Prices
We can rewrite the previous equation as
follows ps ?s ?s ?s ?s ?s
This shows that the pure security price is
determined by the probability that the state
occurs, the present value of a risk-free future
payment of one dollar, and a risk adjustment
factor. The product of the first and third terms
can be called the risk-neutral probability. For
a security with much undiversifiable risk, its
expected return will be large, the risk
adjustment term in square brackets will be small,
and the pure security price will be small
(holding ?s fixed).
11
Optimal Portfolio Choice
  • Assume a perfect and complete market of pure
    state securities exists. How do investors choose
    shareholdings?
  • - ps prices of pure securities
  • ?s state probabilities
  • Qs number of pure securities
  • C0 consumption at time 0
  • W0 wealth at time 0
  • 2. Investors maximize the utility of current
    consumption and future wealth (which will be
    consumed), subject to the constraint that current
    consumption and the value of securities purchased
    does not exceed present wealth.
  • The Lagrangian is
  • Note There is no explicit time discount here but
    this could be done explicitly or within the
    utility function. Also, the pure security prices
    include an implicit market discount rate.

12
The first order conditions for C0, each pure
security S, and ? for each S 3. An
interesting result is that This says that
optimization requires that I set the expected
marginal rate of substitution of consumption for
each security S, equal to the price of S, for all
securities. That is, the utility value I expect
to give up now by reducing consumption now and
buying security S, should equal the amount I
expect to get in the future if state S occurs,
the security pays off 1 and I then consume that
dollar (in the two period case).
13
It is clear that pure security Ss price reflects
both the probability that state S occurs and the
utility value of a dollar payoff in state S. 4. A
related result gives the expected MRS between
states This says that optimization requires
that I set the expected marginal rate of
substitution of security S for each security t
equal to the ratio of the securities
prices. This result is simply a reflection of
the fact that each securitys value is measured
in consumption terms. Once we have the first
result, the second follows from the maximization,
otherwise, we could buy securities that are
cheap in terms of the expected utility of
consumption and sell the expensive ones to
improve our total utility.
14
Results for an Economy of Many Consumer/Investors
  • Pareto Optimality - if all consumers perceive
    the state probabilities the same way (homogeneous
    expectations), we can see from the previous
    result that the actual MRS (not just the
    expected) between any two states will be the same
    for all investors. We know the actual MRSs
    between states are equalized because each
    investor knows what he will get in each state
    because he knows his portfolio of state
    securities.
  • This is Pareto Efficient no one can benefit
    from further security trading (risk sharing).
  • Here again, the information transmission of the
    price system is at work. Because everyone faces
    the same prices, in general equilibrium,
    everyones MRS must be equal or else trading
    occurs, prices change, and at least one person
    ends up better off at the new prices and no one
    else is worse off.
  • Risk separation - with Pareto optimality,
    individual risk preferences are equalized at the
    margin (there is one price for risk) so the
    specific risk preferences of any one investor
    should not affect a firms investment decisions.
    Managers maximize expected NPV.
  • Once risk is traded through the securities
    markets, there is one price for risk. Both
    managers and investors use it to make their
    investment decisions.

15
3. If we assume everyone has a utility function
with the same constant relative risk aversion
coefficient (strong assumption) and the same rate
of time discount, then growth rates of
consumption will be equalized across states and
time (CCAPM). 4. From the previous result, we can
rearrange and for all investors I and j we
have This says that the ratio of marginal
utilities of consumption across investors I and j
is equal for all states (I.e., independent of the
state). From the above equation, if aggregate
consumption is larger in state s than state t,
then everyone must consume more in state s than
state t to keep the ratios across individuals
equal. Thus, any two states yielding the same
aggregate consumption are identical (consumers
make the same consumption choices in both
states).
16
5. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CCAPM) prices assets using consumption as a
primitive to replace the market portfolio used in
the usual CAPM. The intuition behind the CCAPM is
that the amount of aggregate consumption in a
state can be used to define the outcome of the
state. To see this more clearly, use a previous
result and assume that ?s ?t , then This
holds for all consumer/investors. When aggregate
consumption is larger in state s than in state t,
then this implies that the marginal utility of
consumption is smaller in state s than in state
t, so that the price of a pure security for state
s is smaller than that for state t. Thus
aggregate consumption is said to be a sufficient
statistic for state outcomes. This assumes that
utility is not state dependent. That is, only the
amount of consumption matters. For example, if
the only two states are sunny-consume-20 and
rainy-consume-21, you must be better off in the
rainy state because you get to consume more. The
fact that it is rainy should have no effect on
your utility.
17
Maximizing the Value of the Firm
  • How do firms decide which investments to make and
    how many pure securities to issue to finance
    their investments?
  • Assume complete and perfect markets so that
    firms production decisions dont affect market
    prices for securities or the completeness of the
    market.
  • - Qjs ?j(Ij, s) a production function for
    firm j. Transforms current investment into future
    state contingent consumer goods.
  • - Ij investment by firm j
  • - Yj value of the firm
  • The first order condition is
  • This says that the firm should continue to invest
    an extra 1 (increase I) as long as the summation
    over all states, of the output in each state
    times the price of output in each state, exceeds
    the 1 investment. ps ps/(1 E(Rs)) from
    earlier slide so discounting is in price.

18
  • Example Consider two firms with the following
    data.
  • Firm A gt stock price 62, Investment cost 10
  • Firm B gt stock price 56, Investment cost 8
  • States Payoffs Payoffs on Stock on
    Investment Firm A Firm B Firm A Firm B
  • 1 100 40 10 12
  • 2 30 90 12 6
  • First find the pure securities prices as before.
  • 100p1 30p2 62
  • 40p1 90p2 56
  • gt p1 0.5 and p2 0.4
  • Use these to find the NPVs for each investment
    using the first order condition given above.
  • NPVA 10p1 12p2 I 10(0.5) 12(0.4) 10
    -0.2
  • NPVB 12p1 6p2 I 12(0.5) 6(0.4) 8
    0.4
  • Firm A should reject its investment and firm B
    should accept.
  • Question If the pure security prices are p1
    0.3 and p2 0.6, (util max. set these), what
    should the firms do? How about if the investment
    payoffs increased by 10?

19
These results illustrate how the market price of
a firms securities signals investor preference
for its payoffs. Firms make more or less
investments depending upon their technologys
ability to produce payoffs in states that
consumers consider valuable.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com