New policy guidance on European merger control - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 42
About This Presentation
Title:

New policy guidance on European merger control

Description:

Important guidance in EDP/GDP, GE, Tetra, Cementbouw and easyjet judgements ... Certainty of implementation and effective monitoring particularly required (easyjet) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:293
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 43
Provided by: Ditt65
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: New policy guidance on European merger control


1
  • New policy guidance on European merger control
  • Dr Johannes Luebking
  • Deputy Head of Merger Control
  • Communication, Information, Media
  • DG Competition
  • The views expressed are personal to the speaker

2
Guidelines on non-horizontal mergers

3
Non-horizontal mergers General principles
  • No presumption of legality of non-horizontal
    mergers. Balance of probabilities standard
    applies.
  • Non-horizontal mergers are generally less likely
    to create competition concerns than horizontal
    mergers
  • no loss of direct competition between the merging
    parties
  • possible complementarity of merging parties
  • Scope for efficiencies, incl. pricing
    efficiencies (elimination of double mark-ups
    Cournot effect)
  • however, there are circumstances in which
    non-horizontal mergers may change the ability and
    incentive to compete on the part of the merging
    company and the competitors in ways that cause
    harm to consumers
  • Convincing evidence required to support finding
    of harm
  • Particularly important when chains of cause
    and effect are dimly discernible, uncertain and
    difficult to establish (Tetra, par 44)

4
Market share andconcentration levels
  • No threat to effective competition unless the
    merged entity has significant market power, which
    does not necessarily amount to dominance, in at
    least one of the markets concerned.
  • Safe harbours
  • Commission unlikely to identify competition
    concerns when in each of the markets concerned
  • Market share merged entity
  • HHI
  • (Except where certain special circumstances are
    present which make market shares / HHI less
    informative)
  • No presumption of illegality above the safe
    harbours. Need for a case by case assessment.

5
Vertical mergers theories of harm
  • Non-coordinated effects
  • Main concern foreclosure
  • any instance where actual or potential rivals
    access to supplies or markets is hampered or
    eliminated as a result of the merger, thereby
    reducing these companies ability and/or
    incentive to compete and harming consumers as a
    consequence (par 18)
  • Two forms
  • Input foreclosure
  • Customer foreclosure
  • Other non-coordinated effects
  • Access to sensitive information regarding rivals
    upstream or downstream activities
  • Co-ordinated effects

6
Analytical framework
  • Commission will examine
  • Ability to foreclose
  • Incentive to foreclose
  • Likely impact on effective competition

7
Example Input foreclosure
Efficiencies?
Raising rivals costs?
? Net effect on consumers ?
8
(i) Ability to foreclose
  • Necessary conditions for the merged entity to
    have the ability to foreclose
  • the input must be important (e.g. in cost or
    technology terms)
  • merged entity must have market power upstream
  • E.g. other upstream rivals are less efficient,
    offer less preferred alternatives, cannot expand
    easily
  • Input foreclosure may also expose downstream
    rivals to independent upstream suppliers with
    increased market power
  • Check possible counter-strategies of downstream
    rivals

9
(ii) Incentive to foreclose
  • Incentive depends on the degree of profitability
    of the foreclosing practice
  • Merged entity faces possible trade-off between
  • profit loss due to no longer supplying to
    downstream rivals and
  • profit gain due to expanding sales downstream
    and/or being able to raise price in that market
  • Incentive to foreclose may be higher in case
  • Profits upstream are low (compared with
    downstream)
  • Possibility to expand downstream high
  • Merged entity has high market share downstream

10
Ilegality as a disincentive
  • Obligation to examine unlawfulness of conduct as
    a disincentive
  • The Commission has to examine both the incentives
    of the merging parties to adopt a conduct and the
    factors liable to reduce, or even eliminate,
    those incentives, including the possibility that
    the conduct is unlawful.
  • That appraisal, however, does not require an
    exhaustive and detailed examination of the rules
    of the various legal orders which might be
    applicable and of the enforcement policy
    practised within them. (Tetra pars 75-78)
  • Elements that the Commission will take into
    account, on the basis of a summary analysis, to
    assess whether the illegality of a conduct is
    likely to significantly disincentive the merged
    entity (par 44)
  • (i) likelihood that the conduct would be
    clearly, or highly probably, unlawful,
  • (ii) likelihood that the conduct could be
    detected, and
  • (iii) the penalties which could be imposed.
  • Examples
  • GDP/ENI/EDP EON/MOL
  • Thales/Finmecanica

11
(iii) Likely impact on effective competition
  • Effect impede effective competition in the
    downstream market
  • Merger may raise rivals costs (e.g. increase
    input prices) thereby causing an upward pressure
    on rivals prices. This may in turn allow the
    merged entity to raise price
  • Effect more likely to be significant when
    proportion of foreclosed rivals is high or
    foreclosed rivals are close competitors
  • Merger may allow merger entity to raise entry
    barriers
  • In particular, if foreclosure establishes need
    for two-level entry.

12
Effects the SIEC test
  • New test introduced to
  • Consolidate an effects based approach in merger
    assessment
  • Eliminate possible enforcement gaps
  • Impact of the new test for non-horizontal
    mergers
  • No need to establish dominance in the market
    downstream
  • Need to establish likelyhood of significant
    impact in effective competition (e.g. price
    increase)

13
Effects where?
  • Competition policy protects competition, not
    competitors. Consumer welfare standard is well
    established.
  • Problem in vertical mergers some firms are both
    customers and competitors to the merged entity
  • Principle Commission will focus on the effect on
    customers immediately below the merged entity
    (par 16)

14
  • Example Siemens/ VA Tech (M.3653)

VA Tech (ETR) Electrical traction
Siemens Electrical traction
Siemens Rail vehicles
CAF
Even if the non-integrated suppliers of rail
vehicles, including the main non-integrated
supplier CAF, were eliminated from the market for
electrical rail vehicles, there would continue to
be in the individual Member States a sufficiently
large number of actual and potential competitors
in the overall train market.
15
Effects efficiencies
  • Efficiencies can counteract adverse effects on
    competition
  • General principles apply
  • to be identified by the merging parties
  • be verifiable / be merger-specific/ benefit
    consumers
  • Specific efficiencies to vertical mergers
  • Internalisation of double mark-ups
  • Reduction of inventories costs (e.g.
    co-ordination of production and distribution)
  • Alignment of incentives (e.g. increased
    investment in distribution)

16
Conglomerate mergers
  • Theories of harm
  • Focus on anti-competitive foreclosure, through
    tying and bundling
  • common practices, that often have no
    anticompetitive consequences
  • in some circumstances they may deter entry or
    harm consumers by reducing the rivals ability or
    incentives to compete
  • No stand-alone  portfolio effects  theory of
    harm
  •  the fact that the merged entity will have a
    broad range of products does not, as such, raise
    competition concerns 
  • Three-step analytical framework
  • ability / incentives / effects
  • including assessment of efficiencies e.g. Cournot
    effects economies of scope.

17
Next steps
  • Public consultation on draft ended on 12 May
    2007.
  • 32 comments received. They are available at
  • http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/legis
    lation/non_horizontal_consultation.html
  • Commissions adoption of definitive version
    expected by November 2007

18
The new remedies policy

19
Reasons and objectives of review
  • Reflect conclusions from Commissions Merger
    Remedies Study (2005)
  • http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/studi
    es_reports/remedies_study.pdf
  • Incorporate recent jurisprudence
  • Important guidance in EDP/GDP, GE, Tetra,
    Cementbouw and easyjet judgements
  • Reflect experience gained in recent Commission
    practice
  • Relevant recent remedies cases such as
    Inco/Falconbridge or GDF/Suez
  • Update with regard to changes introduced in 2004
    Merger Review
  • Mainly concerns options to extend deadlines to
    discuss and assess remedies

20
General Principles
  • Allocation of responsibilities (EDP/GDP/ENI,
    GE/Honeywell)
  • Commission informs the parties of the competition
    concerns identified
  • It is for the parties to propose remedies,
    Commission cannot unilaterally impose conditions
  • Commission has to assess the effects of the
    operation, as modified by the remedies
  • Commission has eventually to prove that remedies
    are not sufficient to remove competition concerns
  • Proportionality (Cementbouw)
  • Parties do not need to submit remedies that go
    further than what is necessary to remove
    competition concerns
  • If they do so, however, Commission cannot reject
    them and impose different ones

21
General Principles
  • Assessment standard (GE/Honeywell, easyjet)
  • Commitments have to eliminate competition
    concerns entirely and to be comprehensive and
    effective from all points of view
  • Certainty as to the implementation
  • Probability as to the assessment of the operation
    (more likely than not that the operation
    modified significantly impedes effective
    competition)
  • Appropriateness of different types of remedies
  • Divestitures generally preferred, including for
    non-horizontal concerns
  • Other structural commitments, such as access
    remedies, acceptable if same effect as
    divestiture divestitures as benchmark
  • Where market structure is affected only by future
    behaviour of the merging parties, also other
    remedies may have to be assessed (Tetra)
  • Commitments on future behaviour, however, only
    exceptionally accepted. Certainty of
    implementation and effective monitoring
    particularly required (easyjet)

22
Conclusions of the Remedy Study on divestitures
23
Divestitures. Scope
  • Insufficient scope of the divested business is
    the major source of remedy failure (remedies
    study).

24
Divestitures. Scope
  • All assets and personnel necessary to ensure
    viable and competitive business to be transferred
  • Independent access to supply (Inco/Falconbridge
    GDF/Suez Evraz/Highveld), IP rights,
  • Shared assets (duplication, if necessary) and
    personnel to be transferred
  • Modalities
  • Preference for stand-alone business
  • Carve-outs acceptable
  • Risks for viability and competitiveness to be
    limited by requiring transfer of a stand-alone
    business carve out started in interim period
  • Reverse carve out as option
  • Divestiture of individual assets, brands,
    licenses, re-branding
  • Acceptable in exceptional circumstances
  • If resulting business will be immediately viable
    in hands of suitable purchaser
  • In case of doubts concerning purchaser or
    licensee, fix-it-first or up-front solution
    preferable
  • Alternative divestitures (Crown jewels)
  • In case of uncertainties for business to be
    divested, parties can propose alternative
    divestiture, to be implemented if the first one
    does not take place in a short deadline.

25
Divestitures. Additional information requirement
  • There is a clear asymmetry of information on the
    right scope of viable business Commission has
    the burden of motivation to reject commitments
  • New information obligation of the parties in the
    Implementing Regulation Form RM
  • Nature and scope of commitments offered
  • Conditions for their implementation and
  • Suitability to remove any impediment to effective
    competition
  • Deviations from Commissions Model Texts
  • For divestitures, in particular, detailed factual
    description required on how the business is
    currently operated to be compared with scope of
    Divested Business as offered in the commitments

26
Divestiture. Purchasers
  • Divestiture only effective once business is
    transferred to suitable purchaser
  • Suitable purchaser to be agreed within fixed
    time-limit
  • Normal procedure.
  • Multitude of purchasers available (also including
    special purchaser requirements)
  • No specific issues interfere with divestiture
  • Up-front buyer
  • Uncertainty of implementation
  • Obstacles for divestiture, e.g. third party
    rights
  • Uncertainty that Business will attract suitable
    purchaser
  • Difficult interim preservation
  • If high risk of degradation
  • Fix-it-first remedy
  • Preferable where identity of purchaser is crucial
    for effectiveness of remedy
  • E.g. if viability is ensured by specific assets
    of the purchaser (Inco/Falconbridge) or where
    purchaser needs to have specific characteristics
    (tele.ring)

27
Divestiture process
  • Short divestiture two-step process (normally 63
    months)
  • Interim preservation and hold separate
    obligations
  • Monitoring Trustee
  • Timely appointment as up-front trustee
  • Trustee explicitly responsible for third party
    complaints
  • Publication of identity and tasks
  • Hold-separate manager
  • Clear definition of role in commitments
  • Immediate, up-front appointment
  • Supervision/removal by Trustee

28
Non divestiture remedies
  • Removal of links with competitors
  • Divestiture of minority shareholding or,
    exceptionally, waiving rights related to minority
    stakes
  • Termination of distribution or other contractual
    arrangements
  • Access commitments
  • Granting of non-discriminatory access to
    infrastructure, networks, technology/IP rights or
    essential inputs.
  • Acceptable, to lower barriers to entry or
    eliminate foreclosure concerns, if same effect
    as divestiture
  • For lowering entry barriers
  • Ex. pay-TV platforms airport slots gas release
    programs
  • Likely entry of new competitors
  • For foreclosure concerns
  • Access to pipelines, telecom networks, telematics
    networks
  • Likely use by competitors
  • For foreclosure concerns by IP rights or key
    technology
  • Granting of non-exclusive licenses
  • Ex. GE/Instrumentarium Axalto/Gemplus
  • Monitoring of such commitments
  • Self-enforcement of commitments via market
    participants
  • Via arbitration clauses (ARD, easyjet)
  • By national regulators

29
Non divestiture remedies
  • Other non-divestitures
  • To be assessed on a case-by-case basis (Tetra)
  • May be accepted in specific circumstances, such
    as conglomerate concerns
  • Difficulty of monitoring and risks of
    effectiveness they may only amount to mere
    declarations of intentions

30
Procedure Phase I remedies
  • Remedies have to rule out serious doubts.
  • Only acceptable when competition problem is
    readily identifiable and can easily be remedied
    (recital 30 ECMR).
  • To be submitted within 20 WD (extension 10 WD)
  • Only limited modifications acceptable after
    deadline (Philips)
  • Commission will offer opportunity to withdraw
    remedies if concerns finally not arise in one or
    more markets

31
Procedure Phase II remedies
  • Remedies must remove competition concerns
  • They should be submitted before day 65
  • If submitted before day 55, no extension
  • If submitted after day 55 or before day 55 but
    modified version submitted after, extension of 15
    WD.
  • Art 10.3 extension possible
  • Late modified remedies in phase-II
  • Commission not obliged, but allowed to accept
    late remedies (i.e. modified remedies submitted
    after day 65). (Edp/GDP/Eni)
  • Conditions described in Remedies Notice
  • Modified remedies fully and unambiguously remove
    competition concerns without need for further
    investigation or market test
  • Commission must be able to properly consult with
    Member States, (i.e. to keep 10 WD deadline)
  • No Art 10.3 extension will normally be granted
    after day 65

32
Next steps
  • Public consultation on draft ended on 29 June
    2007
  • 23 Comments received. They are available at
  • http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/legi
    slation/merger_remedies.html
  • Commissions adoption of definitive version
    expected by early 2008.

33
  • The Consolidated Jurisdictional Notice

34
Scope and Sources
  • Consolidation of current jurisdictional Notices
  • Concept of Concentration
  • Joint Ventures
  • Undertakings concerned
  • Calculation of Turnover
  • Covers all issues relevant for Commissions
    original jurisdiction under Merger Regulation
  • Sources for review
  • New Merger Regulation
  • Recent jurisprudence, i.e. Cementbouw and Endesa
  • Decisional practice of Commission
  • Adopted on 10 July 2007

35
Concentration
  • Acquisition of control by investment funds
  • Normally
  • Investment company acquires indirect control
    under Article 3 (1), (3)
  • Investment company indirectly holds rights in
    portfolio companies under Article 5(4)
  • Consequence turnover of all portfolio companies
    is taken together, even if held by different
    funds organised by same investment company

36
Concentration
  • Object of control
  • Assets constituting a business with market
    presence
  • Outsourcing cases Concentration only if
  • Transfer of assets and/or personnel
  • That allow acquirer to develop market presence
    beyond outsourcing client
  • Time-frame similar to start-up period for
    full-functionality of JVs

37
Concentration
  • (Joint) acquisition and immediate split-up of
    target
  • Separate concentrations if
  • Legally binding agreement on break-up
  • No uncertainties that second transaction takes
    place within short time-frame
  • Maximum normally 1 year

38
Concentration
  • Parking/warehousing transactions
  • Interim purchaser acquires target on behalf of
    ultimate purchaser on basis of agreement on
    future on-sale
  • Often major part of economic risk shifted to
    ultimate purchaser who may be granted specific
    rights
  • First transaction considered first step in single
    concentration comprising lasting acquisition of
    of (parked) target by ultimate purchaser
  • First transaction no concentration in its own
    right and not considered to fall under Article
    3(5)

39
Concentration
  • Interrelated transactions when are several
    transactions considered one concentration?
  • Under Article 3 Cementbouw, recital 20
  • Transactions unitary in nature
  • Transactions de jure or de facto interconditional
  • Only if control is acquired by same
    undertaking(s), not in cases of assets swaps or
    de-mergers of JVs
  • Examples
  • One business, one economic entity
  • Parallel (EQT/HR/Dragoco) or serial acquisition
    (Kingfisher)
  • Under Article 5(2)(2)
  • Successive transactions between same parties
    within two-year period considered one
    concentration for calculation of turnover
  • Assessment under Article 3 is precedent

40
Types of control
  • Sole control comprises
  • Positive sole control
  • Negative control by minority shareholder
  • De facto sole control on basis of past voting
    pattern and prospective analysis
  • Joint control more on commonality of interests
    and de facto situations
  • Reduction in number of shareholders
    concentration only if change from joint to sole
    control

41
Joint Ventures
  • Distinction between
  • Joint acquisition of control of existing
    undertaking, falling under Article 3(1)
  • Creation of a JV, falling under Article 3(4)
  • Clarification of full-functionality criteria

42
Community Dimension
  • Relevant date for establishing jurisdiction
    Earlier of
  • Date of notification to Commission or national
    competition authorities
  • Conclusion of agreement, announcement of public
    bid, etc.
  • Turnover calculation
  • Normally based on audited accounts of previous
    financial year
  • Adjustments to be made in case of permanent
    changes in economic reality of undertakings
    concerned (CFI in Endesa)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com