Title: Lecture VI: PrincipalAgent Models
1Lecture VI Principal-Agent Models
- Recommended Reading (beyond syllabus)
- Milgrom Roberts, Economics, Organization
Management, Chs 6, 7, 12.
2Lecture VI Principal-Agent Models
- The Problem
- Delegation leads to agency loss
- Undercuts efficiency, offsets gains from trade or
specialization - Sources
- Divergent preferences
- Information Asymmetry expertise,
- In Stroms (2000) terms
- Ex ante Hidden Information (adverse selection)
- See Akerlof (1970)
- Ex post Hidden Action (moral hazard)
- See Grossman Hart (1983)
3Lecture VI Principal-Agent Models
- Solutions (again, Strom)
- Screening
- Revelation of type
- Contract Design
- Incentive compatibility
- Monitoring
- Reduce information asymmetry
-
- Institutional checks
- veto power
- competition
4Akerloff The Market For Lemons
- Information asymmetry undercuts efficient
exchange - Creates divergence between price quality
- Bad quality drives out good until market
collapses - Example market for used cars
- Some fraction, q, cars are good, 1-q are lemons
- People prefer good cars to lemons
- Only know if you own a lemon after sale driving
it - Thus, we expect used car market to have gt 1-q
lemons. If a used car were good, why is it for
sale. at that price?
5Akerloff The Market For Lemons
- Two types of traders, with utility functions
- U1 M ?xi
- U2 M ?3/2xi
- where,
- xi is utility from the quality of the ith car
- M is utility from other goods
- M costs 1 unit (say 1)
- Type 1s own all N cars
- Car quality, x U0, 2 observed only by type
1s
6Akerloff The Market For Lemons
- Type 2s get more utility from cars than type 1s
- A type 1 could sell a car to a type 2 for a
price, p ?(1, 3/2) - Type 1 surrenders 1 unit of x, but can afford gt 1
unit of M - Type 2 surrenders p units of M, buts gets more
utility from x - But as Type 1s MRS between M x 1, type 1s
sell only x lt 1p
x lt 1 put up for sale ? µx-used 1/2
x 1 not put up for sale
0
2
µx 1
7Akerloff The Market For Lemons
- Average quality of cars on market is p/2
- Type 2s willing to trade up to p 3/2 p/2
3p/4 - This price does not compensate Type 1s enough
- Bad quality good drive out good market collapses
x lt 1 put up for sale ? µx-used 1/2
x 1 not put up for sale
0
2
µx 1
8Akerloff The Market For Lemons
- Bad quality good drive out good market
collapses adverse selection - More realistically
- (Low) Price of used good reflects information
asymmetry as well as wear tear - Given low resale price, less of good offered for
resale inefficient
9Adverse Selection Politics
- How do voters know if politician is honest?
- How does PM know if Cabinet Minister is loyal?
- How do party delegates know which leadership
contestant is a winner? - Is applicant to civil service competent,
discrete, non-partisan?
10Technology of Adverse Selection
- Already introduced Signalling game
- Agent (type 1, 2, N) send costly signal
- Principal updates on type via Bayes Rule (if
possible) - Pooling
- Separating
- Semi-separating
- Low quality agents want to pool principal wants
agents to separate - Incentive compatibility Principal can structure
contract (i.e. payoffs) to compensate high
quality but not low quality agents for costly
signalling.
11Moral Hazard
- No types here, but information asymmetry still a
problem - Agent has incentives for ex post opportunism
shirking, sabotage - Political Examples
- Ministers prefer to coast (i.e., shirk) rather
than advance potentially controversial policies
(Dewan Myatt 2007) - Bureaucrats undermine political initiatives that
upset a comfortable status quo or maximize
budgets not efficiency (Niskanen 1971) - Coalition partners alter pre-election policy
agreements
12Moral Hazard Typical Game Structure
- Principal delegates production of a good x to
agent in exchange for some payment, p - e.g., Cabinet delegates policy implementation to
civil service provides ministries with budgets
to do so - Production of x is costly to agent
- Political science analog moving policy from sq
to x requires civil servants to exert effort (e)
or move policy from their ideal point - ?UP/?x gt 0, ?UP/?p lt 0 ?UA/?e lt 0, ?UA/?p gt 0
13Moral Hazard Typical Game Structure
- Agent knows more about production process than
principal - Example 1 x effort ?, ? N (µ,s2)
- Example 2 x (1-?)(effort) ?budget, ?
N(µ,s2) - Agent observes ? higher ? allows less effort,
can maintain effort and obtain larger budget
keep surplus, etc. depending on UA - Principal knows f(x) ? N(µ,s2), but sees
only x - Can Principal structure payment scheme to limit
Agents opportunism enhance efficiency?
14Moral Hazard Typical Game Structure
- Typical modelling trick
- Principal is risk neutral in p, Agent is risk
averse in p - Mathematically, UP is linear in p, UA quadratic
in p
UA
Utility
p
UP
15An Example Indridason Kam (2007)
- Puzzle
- Why do PMs reshuffle ministers frequently if
reshuffling only serves to undercut ministerial
experience amplify civil servants
informational advantage? - Argument
- Ministers have incentives to use their portfolios
in manner that runs contrary to PM cabinets
collective interests, e.g., run up budgets to
boost their own profile, make a leadership run,
etc. - By reshuffling ministers, PM can rein in
ministers propensity to deviate from cabinet
PM.
16An Example Indridason Kam (2007)
- PM sets status quo policy, x ??2 w.l.o.g. set
x (0,0) - Mi Mj spend , s0 ? -?, ? where ? is PMs
oversight - s0 alters policy x ? x0 (s0i, s0j)
- PM reshuffles (r 1) or not (r 0)
- Mi Mj spend again, s1 ? -?, ?
- x0 ? x1 (s0i (1-r)s1i rs1j, s0j rs1i
(1-r)s1j) - Payoffs
17An Example Indridason Kam (2007)
- PM utility tied to governments policy
-
- UPM(x0, x1) -x02 - x12
- Mis policy tied to government policy spending
in portfolio -
- UMi(x0, x1) -x02 - x12 ?ix0i (1-r)
?ix1i r?ix1I - where ?i represents Mis preference for spending
over policy
18A Reshuffle Equilibrium
Reshuffle r 1
- Mj is within ? of ?/2
- if Mj can obtain ?/2 in t1, she does so else
Mj spends ? - So would Mi ever spend s0 lt ??
?
s1j
?j 2
s0i
UMj
Shift
t0
t1
19A Reshuffle Equilibrium
In restraining spending at t0, Mi
?
?
- Forgoes spending utility at t0
- Depends on ?
s1j
s1j
- Avoids policy disutility by limiting Mjs
spending at t1 - Depends on ?
s0i
UMi
s0i
Shift
- In equilibrium when
- ? ? (?/6, ?/(2 2/3?6))
20Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
- Theme Another look at the agency drift model set
out by McNollgast. - Question To what extent can bureaucracy
substitute its own discretion for political
instructions ex post? - Argument Political institutions allow
bureaucrats discretion only within limits allowed
by politicians
21Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
- L E bargain over selection of A (Nash
Cooperative Solution) - Policy setting is delegated to A
- A sets policy xA on contract curve normalized to
L 0, E 1 - Either L or E may veto xA
E
A
L
22Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
Utility Functions UA ?A - x xA UE ?E -
1 x UL ?L - x i.e., the higher ?i, the
more the actor is willing to give up in terms of
agency discretion to get some policy
E
A
L
23Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
- Full Information Game
- xA must be closer to both principals than their
respective reservation values, ?E and ?L - Any x further away ?i than provides ui lt 0 veto
?L
xA
L 0
?E
E 1
24Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
- Add uncertainty
- xA xA ?, where ? is a r.v. such that xA ?
0, 1 - Does this change game?
- Not much Within ? ? of veto points, A has some
wriggle room
??
?L
xA
?E
L 0
E 1
??
25Calvert, McCubbins, Weingast (1989)
- Principals capacity to veto, i.e., exert ex post
correct limits agency discretion even in presence
of uncertainty
??
?L
xA
?E
L 0
E 1
??