Title: Assessing Fiscal Sustainability
1Assessing Fiscal Sustainability
- Teresa Ter-Minassian
- Director, Fiscal Affairs Department
- International Monetary Fund
- January 2004
2Overview of the Presentation
- Defining fiscal sustainability
- Specific considerations
- Biases against sustainable fiscal policies
- IMF framework for assessing sustainability
- Description of the sustainability template
- Application of template and stress testing
- Eventual extension to low-income countries
3Fiscal Sustainability
- Literature presents different concepts of fiscal
sustainability but they all stress intertemporal
solvency constraints. - Solvency
- Todays government debt must be matched by an
excess of future primary surpluses over primary
deficits in present value terms. - In practice, there are limits to the magnitude of
policy adjustment that a borrower is willing or
able to undertake. - Thus, it is important to view solvency in
relation to an adjustment path that is
economically, socially, and politically
acceptable, so that default is not a preferred
option.
4Fiscal Sustainability (contd)
- The most accepted operational criterion
requireswith current policies and prospects for
the relevant exogenous variablesthe public debt
to be constant (or declining) over the
medium-term in relation to GDP. - The primary gap measures the improvement required
in the primary balance to ensure the convergence
of the public debt to a stationary level over a
relevant time horizon.
5Fiscal Sustainability (contd)
- Ceteris paribus, the primary gap is higher the
higher the average real interest rate (expressed
in domestic currency) on the public debt and the
lower the real rate of growth of GDP. - Fiscal sustainability assessments are complex.
They involve judgments about future developments
in hard-to-predict variables such as interest
rates, exchange rates, and real GDP growth rates.
6Fiscal Sustainability (contd)
- Fiscal sustainability assessments typically focus
on a medium-term (5-7 years) horizon. However - It may be advisable to extend this horizon
further if a country faces major fiscal pressures
over the longer term, e.g., on account of
demographic trends or other clearly identifiable
factors, such as the depletion of natural
resources, climate changes, etc. - Even if medium-term solvency appears reasonably
assured, a country may face short-term liquidity
constraints. This is especially the case if the
average maturity of the public debt is relatively
short, and refinancing requirements are
correspondingly large.
7Fiscal Sustainability (contd)
- While the focus of fiscal sustainability
assessments tends to be on the gross public debt,
to the extent possible it is desirable to take
into account in the assessment - any liquid financial assets of the government
and - any significant contingent liabilities related
to, e.g., explicit and implicit government
guarantees and pending judicial actions against
the government.
8Comparison of Public Debt Levels in Emerging
Market and Industrial Economies
- Public debt in emerging market economies is now
higher than in industrial countries as a share of
GDP, and is significantly higher as a share of
government revenue. External debt also accounts
for a higher proportion of public debt in
emerging markets.
9Debt Default and Public Debt Ratios
Default often reflects illiquidity. Sometimes
(e.g., Argentina), default occurs when the
government is still capable of servicing the debt
in the short term, but views the primary
adjustment required to ensure longer-term
sustainability as too costly.
10Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal
Policies?
- If unsustainable fiscal behaviors lead to crises
so frequently, why do governments pursue them,
often for extended periods of time? - Political economy factors
- Voters tend to overestimate the benefits of
public spending programs, and to underestimate
their costs - Voters, and therefore politicians, try to shift
the cost of public spending to future
generations - Distributional conflicts hamper tax and
expenditure reforms needed to improve the fiscal
position - Politicians have high discount rates especially
when term limits prevent their re-election.
11Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal
Policies? (contd)
- Market factors
- Because of delays or asymmetries in information,
markets often do not penalize unsustainable
fiscal behavior early enough - Markets may also bet on bailouts (e.g., from
strong neighboring countries, regional blocks, or
international financial institutions) and - The narrowness and underdevelopment of domestic
capital markets may push governments to borrow
excessively in foreign currencies and/or with
short maturities.
12Why do Governments Pursue Unsustainable Fiscal
Policies? (contd)
- Institutional factors
- Weak budgetary institutions can be major
determinants of inadequate fiscal performance - Antiquated procedures, lack of internal controls
in tax administration - Poor budget management systems and practices
- Overbloated, underpaid and under-trained civil
service - Lack of transparency in the management of public
resources - Lack of accountability of public managers.
13IMF Sustainability Framework
- Assessing debt sustainability has become a
central element of the work of the IMF. This
encompasses both the assessments of external and
fiscal sustainability. -
- These assessments are complemented by analyses of
balance sheet vulnerabilities for the private
(financial and non-financial) and public sectors.
14Sustainability Assessments are Inherently
Probabilistic
- Any assessment of sustainability is probabilistic
in nature, as the debt dynamics depend on
uncertain macroeconomic and fiscal developments
and on future movements in asset prices and
returns. - Thus, one should think of sustainability
assessments as analyses of the probability that
debt dynamics become unstable. This points to a
need for stress testing by considering - Alternative scenarios and
- Standard error bands around the baseline.
15Applications of the Framework for Assessing
Fiscal Sustainability
- In countries with moderately high indebtedness
the framework can help identify vulnerabilities
far enough in advance so that policy corrections
can be implemented. - In countries on the brink, or in the midst, of a
crisis the framework can be used to examine the
plausibility of the debt-stabilizing dynamics
articulated in the authorities policies. - In the aftermath of a default the framework can
be used to examine the sustainability of
alternative options for debt restructuring.
16IMF Sustainability Framework
- The framework includes templates for the analysis
of both external and fiscal sustainability, in
four main blocks - a variety of indicators of debt and debt service
- the baseline medium-term projections (with
particular attention to ensuring the consistency
of these projections and greater clarity about
the assumptions) - a set of stress tests for deviations from the
baseline and - a set of alternative scenarios using different
assumptions.
17Framework Templates
- The templates have several functions
- Illustrate the realism of the existing
projections by laying bare the assumptions that
underlie the projected debt dynamics. - Show the evolution of a countrys debt burden
over the medium term under the baseline
projections of growth, interest rates, and fiscal
deficits. - Provide upper-bound estimates of the likely
evolution of the debt stock, showing whether the
debt burden remains reasonable under a variety of
plausible macroeconomic shocks.
18Disaggregation of effects
- The templates model separately the effects of
growth, real interest rate, and exchange rate
movements on public debt and debt service ratios,
to assess their relative importance in terms of
the evolution of the indicators and also for the
stress tests.
19Key Macroeconomic and Fiscal Assumptions
- Real GDP growth
- Inflation rate (GDP deflator)
- Average nominal interest rate on public debt
- Nominal appreciation/depreciation
- Primary balance
- Growth in real primary public spending
20Alternative scenarios
- Attempt to answer the following questions
- What if history (for growth, inflation, interest
rates, primary balance) repeats itself? - What if there is no policy change in terms of
the primary balance? - What if there is a country-specific shock that
results in a downward step adjustment (one
standard deviation) in GDP growth? - What if market expectations or consensus
forecasts (where available) are used to project
the medium term?
21Bound tests
- Using the baseline scenario as a starting point,
consider the following shocks - Separate adverse two-standard deviation shock
lasting two years to the real interest rate, the
real growth rate, and the primary balance. - A combined shock the real interest rate, real
growth rate, primary balance, and exchange rate
are simultaneously subject to a one-standard
deviation shock. - Two different exogenous shocks
- A 30 percent depreciation
- An increase in debt ratio by 10 percent of GDP,
reflecting e.g. the recognition of implicit or
explicit contingent liabilities.
22Bound Tests Calibration
- The magnitude of the individual shocks (two
standard deviations) assumed in the stress tests
was calibrated to mimic movements in growth,
interest rates, and the U.S dollar value of the
GDP deflator observed in the run-up to previous
debt crises. - The two-year one-standard deviation combined
shock is also very much consistent with the
historical evidence on debt crises. - The resulting upper bounds of the debt ratio that
are derived from the bound tests correspond to
approximately a 95 percent confidence interval.
23Additional Features of the Framework
- The template presents a measure of the constant
steady state primary surplus that stabilizes
the debt ratio at its value at the end of the
projection horizon. This indication of the needed
fiscal adjustment effort can be cross-checked
against a countrys historical performance, to
gauge policy implementation credibility. - The framework also tracks gross financing needs,
as a simple way of assessing roll-over risk.
24(No Transcript)
25Retrospective Debt Sustainability Analysis in
Four Capital Account Crises
- The sustainability framework has been applied
retrospectively to the crises in Argentina
(1999), Brazil (1998), Mexico (1995), and Turkey
(1999), to see whether actual outcomes would fall
within the stress test range.
26 27Results of Retrospective Analysis
- The 2001 debt ratio in Argentina turned out to be
slightly above the upper bound of the stress test
range. If the projection had been extended to
2002, the debt ratio would have moved far beyond
the upper bound of the stress test range. - For Turkey, the outcome for 2001 was well above
the upper bound of the stress test range, despite
the beneficial impact of stronger fiscal
adjustment and lower real interest rates than
expected.
28Results of Retrospective Analysis (contd)
- The post-crisis debt ratio in Brazil was at the
upper end of the stress test range, despite a
better-than-expected post-crisis fiscal
adjustment and lower-than-expected real interest
rates. An unanticipated large real depreciation
was the main contributor. - In Mexico, the outturn in 1995 was above the
one-year-ahead program baseline projection,
because of a larger real depreciation, higher
real interest rates, and slower growth than
anticipated, and because of the securitization of
contingent and unfunded liabilities.
Nevertheless, the outturn was within the stress
test range.
29What the Template Will Not Do...
- The framework presents only the implications of
alternative scenarios. It does not provide
probabilities of debt crises this is left for
the user to determine. - Early warning models are being developed, but
still need to be fine tuned in terms of the
balance between failing to identify crises and
generating false alarms. - The template does not indicate what level of debt
is too high. -
- However, a recent IMF empirical study suggests
that there is an appreciable increase in the
conditional probability of a crisis (to about
15-20 percent) when the external debt level rises
over 40 percent of GDP. - The framework does not contain information at the
level of detail needed to fully capture balance
sheet mismatches, which have had a significant
impact on debt financeability (liquidity) in
recent debt crises.
30Balance Sheet Vulnerabilities are also Important
- Attention needs to be paid to
- Liquidity mismatches in terms of the maturity
structure of assets and liabilities - Currency denomination mismatches between assets
and liabilities - Capital structure mismatches, including possible
overreliance on borrowing relative to equity
(such as FDI) - Intersectoral imbalances, such as overreliance on
the domestic banking system as a holder of
government paper. This would weaken banks
balance sheets in a restructuring situation and
would add to contingent liabilities for the
government in the case of a bail-out.
31Where has this framework been applied so far?
- To date, this framework has been applied to most
countries with access to private financial
markets, as well as all users of IMF resources
(except PRGF countries). - Work is underway to extend the framework to
low-income countries (including PRGF), though
there are likely to be some modifications, as the
issues are somewhat different.
32Issues Relating to Possible Extension of
Framework to Low-Income Countries
- Most financing to LICs comes from bilateral
donors and international financial institutions. - Debt of LICs tends to be on fixed and
concessional terms, implying longer repayment
periods. - In order to meet the Millennium Development
Goals, many LICs are likely to require
substantial external financing in the period
ahead. - Thus, the issue of how much additional debt these
countries can afford to accumulate is of critical
importance.
33Issues Relating to Possible Extension of
Framework to Low-Income Countries (contd)
- The serviceability of the debt in LICs depends
more on the willingness of official creditors and
donors to provide net transfers through
concessional loans and grants than on market
sentiment (as reflected in interest rate
spreads). - Vulnerabilities may be more acute both on the
external and domestic sides (e.g., narrowness of
production and export bases policy deficiencies,
poor governance, weak institutions, inadequate
debt management, political developments with
adverse economic consequences such as civil war
and social strife).
34Possible Considerations in Extending the
Framework to Low-Income Countries
- Focus on an NPV measure of debt (rather than the
nominal stock), given that borrowing is in large
part on concessional terms - Look at the ratios of NPV of debt to GDP, exports
and revenue, to address issues of narrowness of
base. - Similarly for debt service, look at the ratio of
debt service to exports and to revenue. - Extend the projection period due to the typically
longer maturity of concessional debt. - Consider the quality of a countrys policies and
institutions in assessing debt sustainability.