Title: Applied Microeconomics
1Applied Microeconomics
2Outline
- Variable and Fixed cost
- Avoidable and unavoidable costs
- Average and marginal cost
- Efficient Scale
- Long and short-run costs
- Durable goods
- Experience curve and TQM
3Readings
- Perloff Chapter 7
- Kreps Chapters 8 and 10
- Zandt Chapter 4 and 8
4Breaking Down Costs
- In the previous lecture we derived the total cost
function, TC(x) - Total cost can be separated into variable cost,
VC(x), and fixed cost, F - Fixed cost can be separated into avoidable fixed
cost FA and unavoidable fixed cost FU
5Variable Costs
- A cost is variable if it depends on quantity
produced - Examples paper costs for a publisher, flour
costs for a baker, bottle costs for a wine-maker
6Fixed Costs
- A cost is fixed if it does not depend on the
quantity produced - Avoidable fixed costs are fixed costs that do not
have to be paid if the firm shuts down - Unavoidable or sunk fixed costs have to be paid
even if the firm shuts down production - The distinction between fixed and variable, and
avoidable or unavoidable fixed costs depends on
the time horizon as we will see
7Total, Variable, and Fixed Costs
8Sunk Costs
- What is wrong with the following statement
- One reasoning for choosing incineration over
containment is that so much money has already
been spent on pursuing the incineration option.Â
If we go with containment, that money will all
have been wasted.
9Sunk Costs
- Sunk or unavoidable costs are cost that have
already been incurred and cannot be undone - Such costs should be ignored when making
production decisions
10Sunk Costs Example
- Suppose a pharmaceutical company owns a piece of
land that it can develop. - The company has two subsequent decisions to make
- At time 0 Whether to sell the land for 0.7M or
build an endostatin plant on it at a cost of
0.9M - At time 1 If it builds the plant, whether to
shut it down, to operate at low capacity, or to
operate at high capacity
11Sunk Costs Example
- The profits from the different outcomes are (in
millions of dollars) - Decision Revenue Cost Profit
- Sell land 0.7 0.0 0.7
- Build, shut down 0.0 0.9 -0.9
- Build, low output 2.0 3.0 -1.0
- Build, high output 3.0 4.1 -1.1
- Hence, at time 0, the company should sell the land
12Sunk Costs Example
- Suppose now that for some reason the decision to
build the plant is made at time 0 - The payoffs to the different strategies at time 1
are (in millions of euros) - Decision Profits Gross of S. C. Net of S. C.
- Shut down 0.0 -0.9
- Low output -0.1 -1.0
- High output -0.2 -1.1
- Hence, the sunk cost does not affect the optimal
decision at time 1 to shut down!
13Sunk Costs
- There are numerous instances where investors (and
governments!) keep on investing in loss-making
project just because they have already wasted a
lot of money on them - The tendency for people to let sunk costs affect
their decisions is called the fallacy of sunk
cost (or the Concorde fallacy or throwing good
money after bad)
14The Mathematics of Costs
- The average cost per unit of output is
AC(x)TC(x)/x - The marginal cost is MC(x)TC(x) in if the cost
function is differentiable - If production can only be made in discrete
quantities, the marginal cost function is
MC(x)TC(x1)-TC(x)
15Total, Marginal, and Average Cost
16Total Cost and Marginal Cost
- The following relationship holds between marginal
cost and total cost - MC(x)TC(x)
- TC(x)0?x MC(s)dsF
- Hence, total variable cost at x is the area under
the marginal cost curve and to the left of x
17Total, Variable, and Marginal Cost
AreaVC(4)
18Average and Marginal Cost Near Zero
- If there is a fixed cost (TC(0)gt0), then average
cost explodes as x goes to zero
limx?0TC(x)/xlimx?0F/x8 - If there is no fixed cost (TC(0)0), then average
cost converges to MC(0) as production tends to
zero limx?0TC(x)/xlimx?0(TC(x)-TC(0))/xMC(0)
19Average and Marginal Cost Near Zero
Fixed Cost
No Fixed Cost
20Relationship Between Marginal and Average Cost
- By taking the derivative of the average cost we
obtain AC(x)TC(x)/x-TC(x)/x2
(MC(x)-AC(x))/x - Hence
- Average cost is increasing (decreasing) whenever
marginal cost is higher (lower) than average cost - If marginal cost crosses the average cost curve,
this is occurs exactly at the quantity where
average cost is minimized
21Efficient Scale
- The output at which the average cost is minimized
is called the efficient scale of production x - With a U-shaped average-cost curve it can be
found where AC(x)0 - Recalling that the marginal cost crosses the
average cost curve exactly at this point gives us
a useful tool for finding this quantity solving
MC(x)AC(x)
22Efficient Scale
23The Time Horizon of Production
- Suppose Boeing Corp. currently is producing
three 747s per month at a total cost of 65M - What would it cost to increase production to six
747s per month? - Depends on the time horizon
- Next month?
- In 12 months?
24The Time Horizon of Production
- Recall that the total cost function, TC(x), gave
the minimum cost of producing x units using the
available technology and the necessary inputs for
this - Implicit in our derivation of this function was
that the quantity of all factors of production
(inputs) could be chosen freely - However, this assumption is not true in the short
run
25The Short Run and Long Run
- The short run is defined as a time horizon such
that the quantity of some of the firms factors
of production are fixed - The long run is defined as a time horizon such
that the quantity of all factors of production
are variable - The time span of both concepts depends on the
particular industry
26Example Long Run
- Suppose a firm want to produce xL units of
output, that it has production function
f(K,L)KL, and that the market prices of K and L
are given by rltw respectively - Solving minK,LKrLw subject to KLxL gives us
KxL, L0, and the long-run total cost
LTC(xL)xLr
27Example Short Run
- Suppose that capital is fixed at K xL, but that
labor is flexible in the short run - If the firm want to increase production to x in
the short run, it solves minLxLrLw subject to
xLL x - Solving gives us KxL, Lx-xL, and the short-run
total cost STC(x,xL)xLr(x-xL)w - If the firm instead want to reduce production to
x- in the short run, cost will be the same as in
the long run STCS(x-,xL)xLr
28Example Short- and Long-Run Total Cost Functions
29Short- and Long-Run Total Costs Functions
- In theory, the following relationships hold for
the short-run and long-run total cost functions
(where xL is the status-quo level of production
and x is the new level) - LTC(x)STC(x,xL)
- LTC(xL)STC(xL,xL)
30Are the Two Relationships Realistic?
- Labor utilization can be increased temporarily by
overtime instead of hiring - Suppliers may be more likely to change prices
over time - Assumes the mix of inputs is such that cost is
minimized at xL, but what if prices of inputs
changes dramatically so that this is not true? - In general, more information is needed about the
firm to verify the assumptions
31Long-Run and Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost
32Multiproduct Firms
- When firms produce more than one output, concepts
such as average cost are not well defined - If production processes are independent, then
each can be treated as a separate firm - If this is not the case, we can have either
economies of scope (cheaper to produce together)
or diseconomies of scope (cheaper to produce
separately) - Empirical studies reveal that refineries, and car
producers have economies of scope, and railroads
diseconomies of scope in passanger and freight
33Durable Assets
- Some assets can be used more than one period
- Buildings and land
- Machines
- Human capital
- Goodwill
- Demand-side assets such as reputation
- In theory, look at the sum of discounted of cash
flows - Accountants use depreciation over time instead of
change in cash-flow at purchase
34Know How
- Firms sometimes learn less costly ways of
producing by experience learning by doing - The experienced curve is a way of modeling this
- In this model total cost depends on current
production x and the cumulative amount produced
before the current period X, TC(X,x) - Empirical support from computer chips with each
doubling of cumulative output of EPROM chips,
average cost falls by 22
35Conclusions
- Total cost can be separated in avoidable and
unavoidable fixed cost, and variable cost - Sunk costs should be ignored when making
production decisions - At the efficient scale average cost is minimized
and marginal cost equals average cost - Short-run total costs are generally equal to the
long-run costs at the status quo level of
production and higher at other levels