Applied Microeconomics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 35
About This Presentation
Title:

Applied Microeconomics

Description:

In the previous lecture we derived the total cost function, TC(x) ... Solving minK,LKr Lw subject to K L=xL gives us K=xL, L=0, and the long-run total ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:118
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 36
Provided by: upf4
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Applied Microeconomics


1
Applied Microeconomics
  • Cost

2
Outline
  • Variable and Fixed cost
  • Avoidable and unavoidable costs
  • Average and marginal cost
  • Efficient Scale
  • Long and short-run costs
  • Durable goods
  • Experience curve and TQM

3
Readings
  • Perloff Chapter 7
  • Kreps Chapters 8 and 10
  • Zandt Chapter 4 and 8

4
Breaking Down Costs
  • In the previous lecture we derived the total cost
    function, TC(x)
  • Total cost can be separated into variable cost,
    VC(x), and fixed cost, F
  • Fixed cost can be separated into avoidable fixed
    cost FA and unavoidable fixed cost FU

5
Variable Costs
  • A cost is variable if it depends on quantity
    produced
  • Examples paper costs for a publisher, flour
    costs for a baker, bottle costs for a wine-maker

6
Fixed Costs
  • A cost is fixed if it does not depend on the
    quantity produced
  • Avoidable fixed costs are fixed costs that do not
    have to be paid if the firm shuts down
  • Unavoidable or sunk fixed costs have to be paid
    even if the firm shuts down production
  • The distinction between fixed and variable, and
    avoidable or unavoidable fixed costs depends on
    the time horizon as we will see

7
Total, Variable, and Fixed Costs
8
Sunk Costs
  • What is wrong with the following statement
  • One reasoning for choosing incineration over
    containment is that so much money has already
    been spent on pursuing the incineration option. 
    If we go with containment, that money will all
    have been wasted.

9
Sunk Costs
  • Sunk or unavoidable costs are cost that have
    already been incurred and cannot be undone
  • Such costs should be ignored when making
    production decisions

10
Sunk Costs Example
  • Suppose a pharmaceutical company owns a piece of
    land that it can develop.
  • The company has two subsequent decisions to make
  • At time 0 Whether to sell the land for 0.7M or
    build an endostatin plant on it at a cost of
    0.9M
  • At time 1 If it builds the plant, whether to
    shut it down, to operate at low capacity, or to
    operate at high capacity

11
Sunk Costs Example
  • The profits from the different outcomes are (in
    millions of dollars)
  • Decision Revenue Cost Profit
  • Sell land 0.7 0.0 0.7
  • Build, shut down 0.0 0.9 -0.9
  • Build, low output 2.0 3.0 -1.0
  • Build, high output 3.0 4.1 -1.1
  • Hence, at time 0, the company should sell the land

12
Sunk Costs Example
  • Suppose now that for some reason the decision to
    build the plant is made at time 0
  • The payoffs to the different strategies at time 1
    are (in millions of euros)
  • Decision Profits Gross of S. C. Net of S. C.
  • Shut down 0.0 -0.9
  • Low output -0.1 -1.0
  • High output -0.2 -1.1
  • Hence, the sunk cost does not affect the optimal
    decision at time 1 to shut down!

13
Sunk Costs
  • There are numerous instances where investors (and
    governments!) keep on investing in loss-making
    project just because they have already wasted a
    lot of money on them
  • The tendency for people to let sunk costs affect
    their decisions is called the fallacy of sunk
    cost (or the Concorde fallacy or throwing good
    money after bad)

14
The Mathematics of Costs
  • The average cost per unit of output is
    AC(x)TC(x)/x
  • The marginal cost is MC(x)TC(x) in if the cost
    function is differentiable
  • If production can only be made in discrete
    quantities, the marginal cost function is
    MC(x)TC(x1)-TC(x)

15
Total, Marginal, and Average Cost
16
Total Cost and Marginal Cost
  • The following relationship holds between marginal
    cost and total cost
  • MC(x)TC(x)
  • TC(x)0?x MC(s)dsF
  • Hence, total variable cost at x is the area under
    the marginal cost curve and to the left of x

17
Total, Variable, and Marginal Cost
AreaVC(4)
18
Average and Marginal Cost Near Zero
  • If there is a fixed cost (TC(0)gt0), then average
    cost explodes as x goes to zero
    limx?0TC(x)/xlimx?0F/x8
  • If there is no fixed cost (TC(0)0), then average
    cost converges to MC(0) as production tends to
    zero limx?0TC(x)/xlimx?0(TC(x)-TC(0))/xMC(0)

19
Average and Marginal Cost Near Zero
Fixed Cost
No Fixed Cost
20
Relationship Between Marginal and Average Cost
  • By taking the derivative of the average cost we
    obtain AC(x)TC(x)/x-TC(x)/x2
    (MC(x)-AC(x))/x
  • Hence
  • Average cost is increasing (decreasing) whenever
    marginal cost is higher (lower) than average cost
  • If marginal cost crosses the average cost curve,
    this is occurs exactly at the quantity where
    average cost is minimized

21
Efficient Scale
  • The output at which the average cost is minimized
    is called the efficient scale of production x
  • With a U-shaped average-cost curve it can be
    found where AC(x)0
  • Recalling that the marginal cost crosses the
    average cost curve exactly at this point gives us
    a useful tool for finding this quantity solving
    MC(x)AC(x)

22
Efficient Scale
23
The Time Horizon of Production
  • Suppose Boeing Corp. currently is producing
    three 747s per month at a total cost of 65M
  • What would it cost to increase production to six
    747s per month?
  • Depends on the time horizon
  • Next month?
  • In 12 months?

24
The Time Horizon of Production
  • Recall that the total cost function, TC(x), gave
    the minimum cost of producing x units using the
    available technology and the necessary inputs for
    this
  • Implicit in our derivation of this function was
    that the quantity of all factors of production
    (inputs) could be chosen freely
  • However, this assumption is not true in the short
    run

25
The Short Run and Long Run
  • The short run is defined as a time horizon such
    that the quantity of some of the firms factors
    of production are fixed
  • The long run is defined as a time horizon such
    that the quantity of all factors of production
    are variable
  • The time span of both concepts depends on the
    particular industry

26
Example Long Run
  • Suppose a firm want to produce xL units of
    output, that it has production function
    f(K,L)KL, and that the market prices of K and L
    are given by rltw respectively
  • Solving minK,LKrLw subject to KLxL gives us
    KxL, L0, and the long-run total cost
    LTC(xL)xLr

27
Example Short Run
  • Suppose that capital is fixed at K xL, but that
    labor is flexible in the short run
  • If the firm want to increase production to x in
    the short run, it solves minLxLrLw subject to
    xLL x
  • Solving gives us KxL, Lx-xL, and the short-run
    total cost STC(x,xL)xLr(x-xL)w
  • If the firm instead want to reduce production to
    x- in the short run, cost will be the same as in
    the long run STCS(x-,xL)xLr

28
Example Short- and Long-Run Total Cost Functions
29
Short- and Long-Run Total Costs Functions
  • In theory, the following relationships hold for
    the short-run and long-run total cost functions
    (where xL is the status-quo level of production
    and x is the new level)
  • LTC(x)STC(x,xL)
  • LTC(xL)STC(xL,xL)

30
Are the Two Relationships Realistic?
  • Labor utilization can be increased temporarily by
    overtime instead of hiring
  • Suppliers may be more likely to change prices
    over time
  • Assumes the mix of inputs is such that cost is
    minimized at xL, but what if prices of inputs
    changes dramatically so that this is not true?
  • In general, more information is needed about the
    firm to verify the assumptions

31
Long-Run and Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost
32
Multiproduct Firms
  • When firms produce more than one output, concepts
    such as average cost are not well defined
  • If production processes are independent, then
    each can be treated as a separate firm
  • If this is not the case, we can have either
    economies of scope (cheaper to produce together)
    or diseconomies of scope (cheaper to produce
    separately)
  • Empirical studies reveal that refineries, and car
    producers have economies of scope, and railroads
    diseconomies of scope in passanger and freight

33
Durable Assets
  • Some assets can be used more than one period
  • Buildings and land
  • Machines
  • Human capital
  • Goodwill
  • Demand-side assets such as reputation
  • In theory, look at the sum of discounted of cash
    flows
  • Accountants use depreciation over time instead of
    change in cash-flow at purchase

34
Know How
  • Firms sometimes learn less costly ways of
    producing by experience learning by doing
  • The experienced curve is a way of modeling this
  • In this model total cost depends on current
    production x and the cumulative amount produced
    before the current period X, TC(X,x)
  • Empirical support from computer chips with each
    doubling of cumulative output of EPROM chips,
    average cost falls by 22

35
Conclusions
  • Total cost can be separated in avoidable and
    unavoidable fixed cost, and variable cost
  • Sunk costs should be ignored when making
    production decisions
  • At the efficient scale average cost is minimized
    and marginal cost equals average cost
  • Short-run total costs are generally equal to the
    long-run costs at the status quo level of
    production and higher at other levels
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com