Title: Applied Microeconomics
1Applied Microeconomics
2Outline
- First-degree price discrimination Capturing all
of consumer surplus - Third-degree price discrimination
Discrimination by group membership - Second-degree price discrimination
Discrimination by self-selection - Bundling
3Readings
- Kreps Chapter 7
- Perloff Chapter 12
- Zandt Chapter 7
- Tirole Chapter 3 (in course package)
- Indiscriminate pricing (1998)
- A Bundle of Trouble (2001)
4Screening
- If the firm knows that buyers have different
valuations, but cannot tell who has which
preferences, it can still price discriminate by
offering bundles that will appeal to different
customers - This is referred to as second-degree price
discrimination, or screening - The firm must avoid personal arbitrage that a
consumer to whom a given bundle is directed
chooses a different bundle
5Example
- Suppose a firm is producing a good at zero cost
and that it has two potential clients, but cannot
tell one from the other - Al has reservation prices 2.5E for the first unit
of the good, and 1E for the second unit - Beth has reservation prices 2E for the first unit
of the good and 0E for the second - The profit maximizing uniform price is __, giving
a profit of __
6Example Non-Linear Pricing
- However, the firm can do better by offering two
different packages - 2 units of the good for __
- 1 unit of the good for __
- With these prices Al will weakly prefer the first
package (to one or two of the second) and Beth
the second - Profit in this case is __
7Example Two-Part Tariff
- Alternatively, the firm could offer a two-part
tariff - A fixed fee of __ for buying from the firm
- A per unit price of __
- With these price, Al will weakly prefer to
consume two units and Beth will weakly prefer to
consume one unit - Profit in this case is __
8Screening
- Different types of screening
- Block pricing
- Quantity discounts
- Two-part pricing
- Tie-in sales
- Nonlinear pricing
- Quality discrimination
9Screening
- Examples
- Telephone, gas, electricity quantity discounts
- Cell phone contracts
- Amusement parks
- Taxi fares
- Computer chips
10Basic Model
- Suppose a firm has constant unit cost c
- Consumers are of two types, a and b (where 0ltaltb)
- Consumers of type a have quasi-linear demand
function Ua(x,T)av(x)-T, where x is quantity
consumed of the good, and T is the cost of
consumption - Consumers of type b have quasi-linear demand
function Ub(x,T)bv(x)-T - We assume that v(0)0, v(x)gt0, v(x)lt0
11Indifference Curves
Tariff
bs indifference curves
as indifference curves
0
x
0
12Basic Model
- The demand functions of the two types are given
by Da(p) and Db(p) where Da(p)gtDb(p) - The consumer surpluses at price p are Sa(p)p?8
Da(s)ds and Sb(p)p?8 Db(s)ds respectively - This means that Sa(p)-Da(p)
- The share of a in the population is q and the
share of b is 1-q - Aggregate demand is D(p)qDa(p)(1-q)Db(p)
13Perfect Price Discrimination
- If the firm can practice perfect price
discrimination, it charges each consumer j the
price pc and a fixed fee ASj(c) - This makes each consumer indifferent between
consuming or not and implies a profit of
p1qSa(c)(1-q)Sb(c)
14Uniform Pricing
- Suppose there is full arbitrage between consumers
so the firm is forced to charge a uniform price - The firm solves maxp (p-c)D(p) with first-order
condition (pu-c)D(pu)D(pu)0 - This gives a profit of pu
15Second Degree P.D. Two-Part Tariff
- Suppose the firm cannot separate the two types,
but uses a two-part tariff Apx to screen them - Suppose also that it is optimal to serve both
types of consumers (this may not be true!) - The highest fee that both types will pay at price
p is ASa(p) (since altb) - This means that the firm solves maxp Sa(p)
(p-c)D(p) with first-order condition
-Da(ps)(ps-c)D(ps)D(ps)0
16Illustration of Two-Part Tariff
0
17Example Two-Part Tariff
- Suppose there are equal shares of two types of
consumers a has demand function Da(p)1-2p and b
has demand function Db(p)2-4p - As consumer surplus at price p is given by
(1-2p)(0.5-p)/2(0.5-p)2 - The firm has unit cost c1/3 and solves maxp
(0.5-p)2(3-6p)(p-1/3)/2 - First-order condition2pS-13/2-3pS-3pS1-4pS3/2
0, pS3/8 - A(4/8-3/8)21/64, profit 1/32 (profit serving
only market b is 1/36)
18Prices and Profits
- The price under perfect price discrimination is
equal to marginal cost, which is lower than the
price under screening, which in turn is lower
than under uniform pricing cltpsltpm - Since p1 gives maximal profit and any uniform
price can be accomplished with a two-part tariff,
it also holds that p1pS pm
19Tie-In Sales
- Customers who buy one product from a firm are
required to make all their purchases of another
product from the firm - Examples
- Xerox copiers and paper or service
- Printers and toners
- The previous model extends to this setting
20Tie-In Sales
- Suppose two types of consumers demands one unit
of the basic good (copier) and x units of the
complementary good (paper) - Suppose also that the market for the basic good
is a monopoly, but the market for the
complementary good is competitive - The firm produces the basic good at cost C and
the complementary good at unit cost c
21Tie-In Sales
- Given that both types are served, the magnitude
of C is irrelevant and the two-part tariff
solution is achieved - The price of the complementary good is pSgtc
- The price of the basic good is lower than if sold
separately with perfect price discrimination
ASa(pS)ltSa(c)
22Two-Part Tariffs with More than Two Types
- A higher fixed fee implies
- Higher revenue per customer
- Less customers willing to pay
- Setting an optimal two-part tariff means trading
off the two forces - With knowledge about demand functions, this can
easily be done using numerical methods
23Non-Linear Pricing
- However, we can achieve an even better outcome
than the two-part tariff if we use non-linear
pricing - This means offering two different price-quantity
packages (Ta,xa) and (Tb,xb) directed at the two
consumers
24Non-Linear Pricing
Tariff
G
A
pq
bs
indifference
curves
F
Isoprofit
lines
E
as
indifference
curve
A
x
25Non-Linear Pricing Problem
- This implies solving the following problem
maxTa,Tb,xa,xb0 qTa(1-q)Tb-c(qxa(1-q)xb)
subject to the following four constraints - av(xa)-Ta av(xb)-Tb (Incentive Constraint a)
- bv(xb)-Tb bv(xa)-Ta (Incentive Constraint b)
- av(xa)-Ta 0 (Participation Constraint a)
- bv(xb)-Tb 0 (Participation Constraint b)
- Note that PCb is implied by ICb and Pca
26Non-Linear Pricing Solution
- Low-demand consumer derive no net surplus (their
p.p. holds with equality), while high demand
consumers derive a positive surplus - The second binding constraint is to prevent
high-demand consumers from buying the low demand
consumers bundle - High demand consumer gets the socially optimal
optimal quantity, xbDb(c), but low demand
consumers less, xaltDa(c) - If q small and b large compared to a could be
more profitable serving only type B
27Quality Discrimination
- Screening can also be done among consumers with
different tastes for quality by offering product
with different price/quality characteristics - Can be modeled using the same technique as for
non-linear pricing, interpreting x as a measure
of quality and c as the cost of quality - Examples
- Train and airline classes
- Insurance companies
- Computer chips
28Bundling
- Selling different products together in packages
- Makes sense when
- Heterogeneous demands some consumers have
relatively high reservation price for good 1,
others for good 2 - Negative correlation between demands if a
consumer has a high reservation price for good 1,
he is likely to have a low reservation price for
good 2 - The firm cannot price discriminate perfectly
29Bundling
- Examples
- Automobile packages
- Vacation travel
- Cable TV
- Restaurants
- Financial bundling capital good financing
- Legal impediments
- Microsoft Internet Explorer and Windows
- Honeywell/GE (aircraft engines/financing)
30Setting
- Suppose a firm is selling two goods, 1 and 2
- A consumers reservation prices for the two goods
are given by R1 and R2 - Without bundling, the firm sets the prices of the
goods P1 and P2 - With bundling, the firm sets a price PB per
bundle containing one unit of each good
31Consumption Without Bundling
For any prices P1 and P2, consumers can be
categorized according to whether they have higher
reservation prices R1 and R2 for one of the
goods, none of the goods, or both of the goods
32Pure Bundling
- With pure bundling only bundles, and not separate
goods, are offered - Consumers will buy the good if and only if R1
R2 PB
33Mixed Bundling
- With mixed bundling both bundles and separate
goods are offered - In this way, some consumers who would not have
bought anything under pure bundling will buy - The drawback is that some consumers who would
have bought the bundle now only buys one of the
goods - Profit is at least as high as under pure bundling
34Example
- Suppose the firm produces two goods, 1, and 2, at
unit cost c0.5 - There are two consumers
- James has reservation prices R1J1 and R2J2
- Karen has reservation prices R1K2 and R2K1
35Example No Bundling or Pure Bundling
- Without bundling the firm should set P12 and
P22 and sell one unit of each good - This would give a profit of 22-20.53
- With pure bundling, the firm could charge PB3
for each bundle - This would give profit 23-40.54
36Example Mixed Bundling
- Suppose there are two more consumers
- Al has reservation prices R1A2 and R2A0.5 and
Beth has reservation prices R1B0.5 and R2B2 - Without bundling the optimal prices would be
P12, P22 giving a profit of 42-40.56 - With pure bundling neither Al nor Beth would buy
the bundle at price PB3
37Example Mixed Bundling
- However, if the goods were also sold separately
at prices P12 and P22, then Al would buy good
1, Beth would buy good 2, and James and Karen
would buy the bundle - This would give a profit of 2322-60.57
38Conclusion
- Second-degree price discrimination or screening
is a way of price discrimination when the firm
cannot distinguish between different types of
consumers - Two-part tariffs is a simple example that
generally gives a per unit price higher than
marginal cost but lower than under uniform
pricing - Screening can also be done using quality
discrimination and tie-in sales - Bundling is useful when consumers have
heterogeneous and negatively correlated
preferences - Under pure bundling only bundles are available,
under mixed bundling also separate goods