Title: Applied Microeconomics
1Applied Microeconomics
- Game Theory I Strategic-Form Games
2Outline
- Strategic-form games
- Dominance and dominance solvable games
- Common knowledge
- Nash equilibrium
- Mixed strategies
- Mixed Nash Equilibrium
3Readings
- Kreps Chapter 21
- Perloff Chapter 13
- Zandt Chapter 9
4Introduction
- So far we assumed that the firm maximizes profit
assuming its competitors remain passive - This is a reasonable assumption if the firm is
one of many small firms as in a competitive
market or if the firm is a monopoly producing of
a good with no close substitutes
5Introduction
- However, in an oligopoly, a market with a few
firms that have some market power, we need to
relax this assumption and allow for strategic
interaction - To model this situation we need a new tool called
non-cooperative game theory
6Example
- Alpha has a local monopoly in the market for a
good and is making a profit of 2 million Euros - Beta is considering entering the market
- If Beta enters the market, Alpha could either
fight by setting a low price or accommodate, by
setting a high price - If Alpha fights, then both firms get a profit of
1 million Euros - If Alpha accommodates, then both firms get a
profit of 1 million Euros
7Example
- We could model this strategic interaction in the
following ways
Extensive-form game
Strategic-form game
Beta
Alpha
8Game Theory
- Game theory
- Cooperative
- Non-cooperative
- Non-cooperative game theory
- Sequential/extensive-form games
- Strategic-form/normal-form games
- Strategic-form games
- Infinite action
- Finite action
9Strategic-Form Games
- Static analysis
- An extensive-form game can be represented in
strategic form - Infinite action or finite action games
- Infinite and finite games
10Examples of Finite Action Games
11Example of an Infinite Action Game
- Three firms, Alpha, Beta, and Gamma,
simultaneously and independently decides an
amount xi to spend on advertisement, where xi is
non-negative - Total sales in the market is 1 and each firm
sells in proportion to its share of total ad
expenditure - Alphas profit is xAlpha/(xAlpha xBeta
xGamma)-xAlpha and Betas is xBeta/(xAlpha
xBeta xGamma)-xBeta, and Gammas is
xGamma/(xAlpha xBeta xGamma)-xGamma
12Concepts
- A strategy si is a complete contingent plan for a
player in the game - Example 1 sifink
- Example 2 si2/9
- A strategy profile s is a vector of strategies,
one for each player - Example 1 s(fink,fink)
- Example 2 s(xAlpha2/9, xBeta2/9, xGamma2/9)
13Concepts
- A payoff function ui(si,s-i) gives the payoff or
utility to player i for any of her strategies si
and any of her opponents strategies s-i - Example 1 U1(fink,fink)0, U1(fink,cooperate)2,
U1(cooperate,fink)-1,U1(cooperate,cooperate)1 - Example 2 UAlpha(xAlpha, xBeta, xGamma)
xAlpha/(xAlpha xBeta xGamma)-xAlpha - Payoffs are ordinal (we could f.i. multiply all
of them by a positive constant without changing
the game), and the players are generally assumed
to be expected utility maximizers
14Strategic Form Games
- A strategic-form game is
- A set of players N1,2,,n
- A set of strategies for each player i
Sisi1,,siJ - A payoff function for each player i ui(si,s-i)
15Predicting Play Dominance
- A strategy si is dominated for player i if there
is some other strategy si that gives a weakly
better payoff no matter what strategies the other
players use, and strictly better payoff for some
s-i si is dominated if there is si? si such
that ui(si,s-i)ui(si,s-i) for any s-i and
ui(si,s-i)ltui(si,s-i) for some s-i - A strategy si is strictly dominated for player i
if there is some other strategy si that gives a
strictly better payoff no matter what strategies
the other players use si is strictly dominated
if there is si? si such that ui(si,s-i)ltui(si,s-
i) for any s-i
16Example
- If we assume that no player would ever play a
strictly dominated strategy, we can sometimes
make predict the strategies that will be played - Is any strategy strictly dominated in any of
these games?
17Iterated Elimination of Dominated of Strategies
- Eliminating strictly dominated strategy rarely
gives precise predictions, but the procedure can
be extended - Suppose we delete all the strictly dominated
strategies from the strategy set S1 of the game
G1 - Once we have done this we get a new game G2 with
strategy set S2 from which we once again can
delete the strictly dominated strategies - We can keep on deleting strategies in this way
until we reach a game Gt with strategy set St
such that no more strategies can be deleted
18Example
- Find the set of strategies that survives iterated
elimination of strictly dominated strategies in
the following game
19Iterated Elimination of Dominated of Strategies
- This procedure is called iterated elimination of
strictly dominated strategies - In finite games (and most infinite games), the
set of strategies that survives iterated
elimination of strictly dominated strategies does
not depend on the order in which we eliminate
strategies! - If only one strategy for each player survives the
procedure, then the game is said to be dominance
solvable
20What Assumptions Would Result in IESDS?
- Deduction If all players know their payoff
function and never play a strictly dominated
strategy, know that their opponent knows his own
payoff function and never plays a strictly
dominated strategy, know that their opponent
knows that they know their payoff function and
never play a strictly dominated strategy etc. - Evolutionary selection Alternatively, we can
assume that players recurrently are drawn from a
large population of individuals to play the game,
and that individuals that perform worse disappear
or change strategy
21Experimental Evidence
- Few subjects play dominated strategies
- More subjects play iteratively dominated
strategies - The more iterations are needed to solve game, the
worse predictive power of IESDS
22Iterated Elimination of Weakly Dominated
Strategies
- The set of strategies that survive iterated
elimination of weakly dominated strategies in
finite action games may depend on the order of
elimination (compare eliminating b and B)
23Nash Equilibrium
- Often many strategies iterative elimination of
strictly dominated strategies - We want to be able to make predictions also in
this case - The most famous concept for doing this is the
Nash Equilibrium
24Nash Equilibrium
- A Nash equilibrium is a strategy profile such
that no player could gain by deviating
unilaterally and play a different strategy - Formally, s is a NE if for all i in N, and all
si in Si, ui(si,s-i)ui(si,s-i) - If the inequality is strict, then s is said to
be a strict NE
25Examples
26Finding Nash Equilibria
- In order to find the Nash equilibria of a game it
is useful to find each players best reply to any
strategy played by the opponent(s) the best
reply correspondence - A NE is a strategyprofile such that allplayers
are playinga best reply
27What Assumptions Would Result in NE?
- Deduction
- Evolutionary selection
- Learning
28Nash Equilibrium and Iterated Elimination
- A strategy that is eliminated by iterated
elimination of strictly dominated strategies
cannot be part of a NE - If the game is dominance solvable, the surviving
strategy profile is the unique NE of the game - If the game is dominance solvable using iterated
elimination of weakly dominated strategies, the
resulting strategy profile is a NE, but there may
be more NE
29Example Without Nash Equilibrium in Pure
Strategies
- Sometimes, there does not exist a NE is pure
strategies - To deal with this we define mixed strategies pi
as probability distributions over the set of pure
strategies in Si - Motivation
- Each player is randomizing
- Game played against a randomly drawn individual
from a large population where a share pi1 play
strategy si1, a share pi2 play strategy si2 etc.
30Example
- Suppose two players are playing the following
game - A mixed strategyfor player onecould be
p1(0.3,0.7) to play A with prob. 0.3 and B
with prob. 0.7
31Nash Equilibrium in Mixed Strategies
- Let ?Si set of all mixed strategies over Si, and
let p be a mixed strategy profile, p(p1,p2,,p3) - Formally, p is a NE if for all i in N, and all
pi in ?Si, ui(pi,p-i)ui(pi,p-i) - Nash (1950) Any finite game has at least one
Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies - Not that pure strategies are just mixed
strategies that play a particular pure strategy
with probability one
32Example
- Find a NE in the above game
- If there is a NE such that player 1 is
randomizing when 2 is playing a with prob. p and
b with prob. 1-p, then player 1 must get the same
expected payoff from both of his strategies - U(A)-2p1(1-p)1-3p
- U(B)1p-1(1-p) 2p-1
- Hence, 1-3p2p-1 or p2/50.4
33Example
- Likewise, if there is a NE such that player 2 is
randomizing when player 1 is playing A with prob.
q and B with prob.1-q, then player 2 must get the
same expected payoff from both of his strategies - U(a)1q-1(1-q)2q-1
- U(b)-1q1(1-q)1-2q
- Hence, 2q-11-2q or q2/40.5
- The NE is thus given by ((qA0.5,qB0.5),((pA0.4,
pB0.6))
34The Best-Reply Correspondence
- Let G be a strategic-form game with players
i1,,n, strategy sets S1,,Sn, and payoff
functions u1,,un - For each player, define player is best-reply
correspondence Bi(s-i) that maps any strategy
choice s-i by the opponent(s) to the most
profitable strategy for player i - Mathematically Bi(s-i)siui(si,s-i)ui(si,s-i
) for all si in Si
35Nash Equilibrium and the Best Reply Correspondence
- We can define a NE using the best-reply
correspondence it is a strategy profile s such
that all players are playing a best reply - Mathematically s is an NE if si?Bi(s-i) for
i1,,n - Hence, the NE can be found using the best-reply
correspondences of all players
36Example Finite Game
- Suppose the column player plays a with prob. Pa
- The row players expected utility of A is then
U(A)2Pa-5(1- Pa)-57Pa - The row players expected utility of B is then
U(B)0Pa0(1- Pa)0 - Hence, A is a best reply for Pa5/7 and B for
Pa5/7 and any randomization over the two for
Pa5/7
37Example Finite Game
38Example Finite Game
- Suppose the row player plays A with prob. PA
- The column players expected utility of a is then
U(a)3PA-5(1- Pa)-58PA - The row players expected utility of b is then
U(b)0PA0(1- PA)0 - Hence, a is a best reply for PA5/8 and B for
PA5/8 and any randomization over the two for
PA5/8
39Example Finite Game
40Example Finite Game
- The NE are given by the points where B1(Pa)PA
and B2(PA)Pa - Graphically this is where the two best-reply
correspondences intersect - Hence, the NE of the game are (PA0,Pa0),
(PA1,Pa1), and (PA5/8,Pa5/7)
41Example Quantity Competition
- Suppose two firms, iAlpha, Beta, are competing
in quantities and simultaneously and
independently decide a non-negative amount xi to
produce (Cournot competition) - Each firm has per unit cost clt1 and the market
inverse demand function is given by
P(xi,x-i)1-(xix-i) for xix-ilt1 and 0 otherwise - Payoffs are given by uAlpha(xAlpha,xBeta)
xAlpha(1-(xAlphaxBeta)-c)uBeta(xBeta,xAlpha)
xBeta(1-(xAlphaxBeta)-c)
42Example Quantity Competition
- To find the best-reply correspondence for firm i
we solve Maxxi0 xi(1-(xix-i)-c)with the
first-order condition 1-(x-ixi)-c-xi0 - Solving for xi gives Bi(x-i)(1-c-x-i)/2 for
1-cx-i and 0 for x-igt1-c - If we plot the best-reply function for both firms
in a diagram, we get the following picture
43Example Quantity Competition
44Example Quantity Competition
- The best-reply correspondences are down-ward
sloping since each firm wants to produce less if
the competitor is producing more quantities are
strategic substitutes - In order to find the NE we solve
xAlpha(1-xBeta-c)/2 xBeta (1-xAlpha-c)/2 - This gives the NE xAlpha xBeta(1-c)/3
45Example Quantity Competition
- This game is symmetric since uAlpha(xAlpha,xBeta)
uBeta(xBeta,xAlpha), implying identical
best-reply correspondences for both firms - Moreover, from the first-order condition we see
that both firms must produce equal amounts in a
NE since xix-i1-(x-ixi)-c - We can use this fact to solve for an NE in a
convenient way xi1-2xi-c gives xi(1-c)/3,
implying a price of p(x)(12c)/3 - Compare this to the monopoly price of p(1c)/2
and the competitive price of pc
46Example Quantity Competition
- Using this technique we can easily solve for the
NE in a market with n identical firms of the same
type - Denoting total quantity by x, we can write the
first-order condition for firm is profit
maximization xi1-x-c - Since all firms will produce equal amounts in a
NE this means xi1-nxi-c or xi(1-c)/(n1) for
all i1,,n - This gives a price of p(x)(1nc)/(n1), that
converges to c as n goes to infinity
47Conclusion
- Game theory is a tool for modeling strategic
interaction - A strategic-form game consists of the players,
the players strategies, and their payoff
functions - Ways of predicting play
- Iterated elimination of dominated strategies
- Nash equilibrium, strict Nash equilibrium
- Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies
- The Nash equilibria can be calculated using the
best-reply correspondences