Title: Next Discussion Session
1Next Discussion Session
- Choices
- Mon, June 7th
- Wed, June 9th
- Mon, June 14th
- Also, review for exam on June 9th, exam June
11th. Covers Chapters 1-9 in Rosen, lecture
material through next Monday. - Practice exam will be posted by 5pm this Friday.
- Answers posted by 5pm Sunday. I will answer
questions during office hours and review session.
2Special Interest Groups
- Recall from last time Community/Group voting
pressure. People are more likely to vote if they
are part of a group that actively encourages
voting (ie. unions) - Further, these people tend to vote the same way
(unions traditionally vote Democratic in the USA) - This implies that these groups exercise a level
of power that individual voters cannot. As such,
there is an incentive to form special interest
groups.
3Special Interest Groups (SIGs)
- SIG members generally share a common trait. SIGs
generally form to encourage politicians to make
policy decisions that benefit the shared
interests of their members. - Example NRA and gun control.
4What are these common traits?
- Level of income people at different income
levels may have different ideas on what programs
to fund. - Industry of Employment Unions, Firm Owners
- Region People in the breadbasket (Kansas,
Oklahoma, etc) have preferences for the level of
farm subsidies - Personal Characteristics AARP, religious groups,
ethnic groups, even gender.
5Lobbyists
- SIGs may hire lobbyists to meet with
politicians. These lobbyists may attempt to
provide information (could it be biased?) on the
state of the world, or they may attempt to offer
campaign contributions or bribes in exchange for
favors.
6SIGs continued
- These groups may engage in rent-seeking behavior,
in order to win favorable outcomes for their
members. It is to be noted that SIGs with
opposing interests may be operating at the same
time in the same legislative body - Tobacco lobbyists spend millions each year
attempting to limit the level of cigarette taxes
imposed by states. - Non-smoker rights groups spend millions each
year trying to promote healthier lifestyles
through banning public smoking and raising
cigarette taxes.
7Who are some of the big SIGs?
- National Rifle Association (NRA) a group that
seeks to protect the constitutional right to bear
arms. Outspoken opponents of gun control. Pay for
pro 2nd amendment publications, lobby, organize
congressional letter campaigns. Members receive
discounts at hotels such as Best Western and
Ramada, rental car companies Hertz and Avis. 4.3
million members.
8Mothers Against Drunk Driving (MADD)
- Group dedicated to ending drunk-driving through
legislative and grassroots action, and
victim-counseling. 47 million dollars of funding
in the 2002-2003 fiscal year. Frequently called
to testify before congressional subcommittees.
Instrumental in helping legislators propose and
enact tougher drunk-driving legislation, etc.
9Chapter 7 Conceptual Issues in Income
Redistribution
10Introduction
- Will provide framework for thinking about the
normative and positive aspects of government
income redistribution policy.
11Introduction
- Some questions whether economists should be
concerned with distributional issues. - Value judgments embodied in the right income
distribution. - No scientific basis for the right distribution.
12Introduction
- Focus on efficiency alone has problems.
- That focus, too, is a value judgment.
- Multiple equilbria.
- Decision makers do care about the income
distribution economic analysis ineffective if it
doesnt consider this policy-maker constraint.
13Distribution of Income
- Can analyze household income, and see how equally
or unequally the pie is distributed. - Table 7.1 shows the percentage of money income
among households for more than 30 years.
14Table 7.1
15Distribution of Income
- Richest 20 receives about 50 of total income.
- Poorest 20 receives about 4 of total income.
- Inequality has increased over time.
16Are the rich getting richer and the poor getting
poorer?
- Most of you have heard this at some point or
another. - Half true. The rich are getting richer. But the
poor are also getting richer. - Inequality is increasing because the rich are
getting more as a of income, relative to the
poor. - Note that using our current definition of the
poverty line, almost everyone in the US would
have been below the line in 1880. Economists
predict that almost nobody will be below this
line in the year 2090.
17Distribution of IncomePoverty
- The poverty line is a fixed level of real income
which is considered enough to provide a minimally
adequate standard of living. - Inherently arbitrary, but still a useful
benchmark. - Trends over time
- Differences across groups
18Quick digression on the poverty line
- Created in 1965 by Mollie Orshansky for the SSA.
- Based on food requirements. Dept. of Ag. (1955)
found that poor families spend 1/3 income on
food. Orshansky estimated the cost of providing a
basic level of nutrition and multiplied by 3. - Note poverty line increases with size of family,
but at a decreasing rate (due to the belief that
there are certain fixed costs in households)
19Absolute vs. Relative poverty lines
- Some debate as to whether or not our poverty line
is appropriate. - Poor families now spend about 1/5 income on food.
- Others have proposed relative poverty lines.
Victor Fuchs (1967) proposed setting the line at
45-50 of the median households income. - US still uses a version of Orshanskys poverty
line.
20Distribution of IncomePoverty
- Poverty line for a family of 4 was 18,244 in
2001. - Median household income more than double that,
42,228. - Table 7.2 shows poverty rates for selected groups
in 2001.
21Table 7.2
22Distribution of IncomePoverty
- Poverty rates in U.S. in 2001 might be considered
surprisingly high 11.7 for population as
whole. - Concentrated among certain groups, such as female
headed households, children, and minorities. - Elderly have lower poverty rates than the U.S.
average.
23Distribution of IncomePoverty
- Can also look at trends over time.
- See Table 7.3
- Poverty considerably lower than in 1960s, but
not much progress since 1970.
24Table 7.3
25Interpretation Problems
- Poverty line ( poverty rate) is subject to a
number of criticisms. - When interpreting the numbers, it is useful to
know the conventions and limitations.
26Interpretation Problem 1
- Income consists only of cash receipts.
- Excludes in-kind transfers like health insurance,
food stamps, and housing. - Would reduce poverty rate by more than 20.
- Excludes non-market work such as childcare or
housework. - Ignores income flow from durable goods.
27Interpretation Problem 2
- Income is before-tax.
- It ignores cash refunds from the Earned Income
Tax Credit, which has grown dramatically in the
last decade, and now amounts to more than 31
billion annually. - Ignoring this overstates poverty rates, and also
affects the trends over time.
28Interpretation Problem 3
- Income is measured annually.
- Not obvious what the correct time frame should
be. - Income does fluctuate from year-to-year.
- Lifetime income considerations seem relevant.
- Consider a starving college student, for
example. Not really poor in a lifetime sense.
29Interpretation Problem 4
- Unit of observation
- Person, family, household?
- People often make decisions as an economic unit,
and there are economies of scale in household
production. - Classifications can matter for poverty numbers
- Bauman (1997) calculates that including the
income of non-family members (such as nonmarried
cohabitors) would reclassify 55 of people who
are poor out of official definition.
30Upshot
- It is quite likely that the official poverty rate
is overstated. - This is not to say that there is no real reason
for income distribution. - Also, just because ones family is officially
above the poverty line isnt to say his family is
doing well for itself. A family of 4 with 19,000
annual income is still in some sense struggling.
31Rationales for Income Redistribution
- Different kinds of social welfare functions
- Utilitarian
- Maximin criterion (Rawlsian)
- Pareto efficient
- Non-individualistic
32Simple Utilitarianism
- The utilitarian social welfare function is
- Which depends on all n members of society. One
specific function form is
- This special case is referred to as an additive
social welfare function.
33Simple Utilitarianism
- With the additive SWF that was given, also
assume - Identical utility functions that depend only on
income - Diminishing marginal utility of income
- Societys total income is fixed
- Implication government should redistribute to
obtain complete equality.
34Simple Utilitarianism
- This can be illustrated with 2 people.
- See Figure 7.1
- Any income level other than I does not maximize
the SWF. - I entails equal incomes.
35Figure 7.1
36Numerical Example
- 2 identical individuals (Betty and Al),
diminishing marginal utility of income. 40 in
economy. - Additive social welfare function
- For example. If Al has 30 dollars and Betty has
10, Social welfare W 21 9 30. - Total Utility is maximized when each individual
receives 20. W 1616 32.
37Simple Utilitarianism
- Striking result is that full income equality
should be pursued, but some scrutiny required. - Assumes identical utilities
- Assumes decreasing marginal utility
- Assumes total income fixed
- E.g., no disincentives from this kind of
redistributive policy.
38The Maximin Criterion
- The Rawlsian social welfare function is
- Social welfare in this case depends only on the
utility of the person who has the lowest utility. - Rawls (1971) asserts it has ethical validity
because of the notion of original position. - Notion that ex-ante individuals do not know where
in the income distribution they will be.
39Original Position
- Rawls proposed a thought experiment
- Individuals start from a position of knowing
nothing about themselves. - They then choose how to organize society.
- The Maximin criterion is what Rawls believes
people would choose for themselves.
40The Maximin Criterion
- These ethical claims are controversial
- Still selfish view in original position
- Individuals extremely risk averse here
- All that is relevant is the welfare of the
worst-off person, even if a policy is extremely
detrimental to everyone else.
41Pareto Efficient Income Redistribution as
Justification for Income Redistribution
- Suppose that utility of richer person does depend
on poorer persons utility. That is
- Government redistribution in this case could
improve efficiency. It may be difficult for the
private market to do this, if, for example, the
rich lack information on just who really is poor. - Simply an externality problem.
42Pareto Efficient Income Redistribution
- Altruism plays a role in this example, but
private market could conceivably give charity. - But not just altruism. Self-interest could play
a role. Suppose there is a possibility that, for
circumstances beyond your control, you become
poor. - When well-off, pay premiums. When bad times
hit, collect payoff. - Motivation of some social insurance programs.
43Nonindividualistic views
- In previous cases, social welfare derived from
individuals utilities. - Some specify what the income distribution should
look like independent of individual preferences. - One example commodity egalitarianism.
- Right to vote, food, shelter, education, perhaps
health insurance.
44Processes versus Outcomes
- All the above examples are concerned with
outcomes of distribution (who ends up with what) - Some argue that a just distribution of income is
defined by the process that generated it. - For example, equal opportunity in U.S.
- Ensuing outcome would be considered fair,
regardless of the income distribution it happened
to entail. - Fair bit of income mobility (Gottschalk, 1997).
- Does raise problem of how to evaluate social
processes.
45Expenditure Incidence- the impact of expenditure
policy on distribution of real income
- Relative Price Effects
- Public Goods
- Valuing In-Kind Transfers
46Relative Price Effects
- Suppose government subsidized housing of the
poor. - As a first pass, redistribution from rich to
poor. - May have overall effects on housing prices
- Landlords may reap part of gain.
- Affects wages of construction workers
- Generally, any government program sets off a
chain of price changes, and the incidence is
unclear.
47Public Goods
- Do rich and poor benefits similarly from the
provision of public goods? - Difficult to measure, sensitive to assumptions
that are made.
48Valuing in-kind transfers
- Government provides many benefits to the poor
in-kind that is, direct provision of goods
rather than cash. - Food stamps
- Medicaid
- Public Housing
- Estimating value is difficult. Not always valued
at dollar-for-dollar (if resale is difficult).
49Valuing in-kind transfers
- Consider how the provision of an in-kind benefit
changes the budget constraint in transparency. - In this case, giving an in-kind benefit lowers
utility relative to an equally costly cash
transfer. - Although the person is better off by having the
in-kind transfer than not having it, she would be
even happier with the cash transfer.
50Valuing in-kind transfers
- A person can never be made better off with an
in-kind transfer that is equal in cost to a cash
transfer. - There are instances, however, when a person is
indifferent between the two transfer schemes. - See overhead.
51Valuing in-kind transfers
- Why give in-kind transfers if they tend to be
inefficient? - Commodity egalitarianism/ tax-payer sovereignty.
Congress (or taxpayers) may only want to provide
health-care or housing, rather than just give
cash. - May reduce welfare fraud (especially if the
in-kind transfer is an inferior good) - Politically viable because they help the producer
of the in-kind good.
52Recap of Income Redistribution Conceptual Issues
- Distribution of income
- Poverty line
- Social welfare functions
- Valuing In-Kind transfers