... exploiting the increase in the legal punishment fo - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 53
About This Presentation
Title:

... exploiting the increase in the legal punishment fo

Description:

... exploiting the increase in the legal punishment for parking violations after Nov ... good driver (lesson group) barely increased the likelihood of ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:94
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 54
Provided by: catiae
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: ... exploiting the increase in the legal punishment fo


1
Lecture 2 Corruption Institutions and
Development - P. Vicente University of
Oxford http//www.pedrovicente.org/Teaching/Oxford
/instdev.htm
2
1 Corruption and Rent-Seeking
  • To introduce both concepts we use an example on
    the financing of a public project (Besley, 2006)
  • Suppose that a community of N individuals has to
    make a single social decision whether to build a
    public project
  • This decision is denoted by with
    denoting the case in which the project
    is constructed
  • If the project is built, the government uses a
    head tax
  • We assume there are two groups of citizens
  • Those who value the project and receive utility
    b from it and those who do not value the project
    (0 utility)
  • The citizens who value the project constitute
    proportion of the population
  • We assume that all citizens have equal income, y
  • The project costs c to implement (assume
    , i.e. each citizen is able to bear the
    per capita cost of the project).

3
  • In order to motivate the presence of the
    government in this problem
  • Suppose the project is to be funded through
    private non-mandatory contributions by each
    citizen (where )
  • If , the project is implemented
    otherwise it is not
  • Any surplus from contributions is divided
    equally across all citizens
  • Analyzing Nash Equilibria of the contribution
    game
  • No citizens apart from those valuing the project
    will contribute for the project
  • No aggregate contribution amount surpassing c
    will arise
  • If then there is always a NE where
    for all citizens - no citizen would like
    to deviate since his gain from the project is not
    enough for him to bear all the cost
  • If , there is a NE with equal
    contributions summing c again, think of a
    deviation by one citizen
  • No provision of the project (market failure)
    comes in this model from a coordination failure

4
  • If indeed it is the government who decides on
    the provision of this project
  • We will see no change in aggregate welfare if it
    decides not to implement it
  • We will see change if the project
    is realized
  • (from having change for all
    individuals valuing the project and change
    for the remaining players)
  • This means that the project is worthwhile if
  • If this condition holds, then any political
    mechanism in which the project fails to go ahead
    can be considered a government failure

5
  • We define corruption as a situation where a
    monetary payment (bribe) is paid to the policy
    maker to influence the policy outcome
  • Suppose the policy maker can earn a private
    monetary rent of for setting
    regardless of whether the project is worthwhile
    or not
  • We assume this payment (fixed for
    simplicity) is a transfer made by a subset of
    organized citizens (think of the lobbying model
    of last lecture for more detail)
  • Suppose that . If this happens,
    the policy maker will always want to implement
    the project, as the rent he receives is higher
    than the per capita contribution to the project
  • The utility of the citizen depends on whether
    they finance the transfer
  • Suppose that a fraction , of citizens
    who derive positive utility from the project,
    finances this transfer on an equal per capita
    basis

6
  • The payoffs are then
  • for the policy maker
    (assuming he derives 0 utility from the project)
  • for those who
    favor the project and pay bribes
  • for those who favor the project
    but do not pay bribes
  • for those who do not favor the
    project
  • Assuming that
    , we have individually rational transfers, so
    that both organized citizens and policy maker are
    better off with corruption

7
  • If corruption increases social
    surplus relative to any situation yielding
  • If we would have corruption
    decreasing aggregate payoff (efficiency)
  • If corruption would only imply a
    change in the distribution of payoffs (not only
    across policy maker and organized citizens, given
    the payment r, but also across those in favor of
    the project and those against, since the project
    would be implemented)
  • The main point here is that corruption does not
    necessarily imply a change in the aggregate
    payoff (efficiency), though there are always
    distributional effects
  • However, if the government is benevolent (e.g.
    in the situation above, where the
    policy maker maximizes his payoff and happens to
    be a citizen who does not favor the project),
    i.e. does the right thing in the absence of
    corruption, then we have efficiency problems
    stemming from corruption

8
  • We now present a version of the classic model of
    rent seeking due to Tullock (1980)
  • Suppose that citizen i can pay to influence
    the policy maker regarding the implementation of
    the project (in favor or against it)
  • Crucially we assume that is a real resource
    cost (e.g. labor time), which cannot be
    appropriated by the policy maker (we assume this
    agent does not get any positive or negative
    payoff from this influence)
  • We assume that each citizen commits resources
    in favor of the project and
    against the project
  • Define and
  • Then assume that the probability that the
    project goes ahead is captured by the function

9
  • In the symmetric Nash Equilibrium of this rent
    seeking game, nobody who favors the project
    commits any resources to influencing against, and
    vice-versa.
  • The payoff of a citizen i who favors the project
    and contributes
  • The payoff of citizen j who opposes the project
    and contributes
  • We now solve for the NE where every citizen puts
    in the same effort level, i.e. we take FOCs of
    the above and equate them

10
  • This means the key magnitude in defining the
    probability that the project is implemented is
    defined by the ratio of the per capita cost of
    construction of the project and the (per
    capita by definition) benefit for those in favor
    of the project b
  • Total expenditure on rent seeking at the
    equilibrium is then (using last expression and
    one of the two FOCs)
  • This implies the following ex-ante surplus at
    the NE

11
  • If , we see that
  • If the project was to be implemented without
    rent seeking, we are now in a worse position
    given uncertainty of implementation and real
    resource costs of influencing
  • If the project was not to be implemented without
    rent seeking, we may have a better aggregate
    ex-post payoff if the project goes ahead and
  • If , and
  • If the project was to be implemented without
    rent seeking, we may be in a better position if
    the project does not go ahead and
  • If the project was not to be implemented without
    rent seeking, we have a lower aggregate payoff
    given the possibility of implementation and the
    costs of influencing.

12
  • If the government was going to do the right
    thing in the first place (benevolent
    government), we can only be in a worse situation
    when we have rent seeking. This is given
  • the possibilities of doing the wrong thing,
    i.e. the same kind of situation we had for
    corruption
  • the additional real costs of influencing that
    help defining rent seeking activities
  • Indeed as defined by Buchanan, Tollison and
    Tullock, 1980, rent-seeking corresponds to
    resource wasting activities of individuals in
    seeking transfers of wealth through the aegis of
    the state
  • Contrasting this definition with the usual
    definition of corruption, abuse of public office
    for private gain, we see that although
    potentially non-intersecting (above examples),
    rent seeking can be seen as an inefficiency
    qualification of certain activities that are
    considered corruption
  • Corruption less well-defined in economics, but
    easier for empirics

13
2 Corruption as an Agency and Competition Problem
  • We start by looking at corruption as an agency
    problem. The analysis here is due to an example
    by Becker and Stigler (JLS, 1974), the first
    economics paper addressing corruption
  • Let p be the probability of detecting
    malfeasance (corruption) at any period
  • b is the monetary value of the gain to
    enforcers (public officials) from malfeasance
  • We take a discount rate r as given
  • Let be outside-opportunity earnings for
    enforcers at time i of their career
  • The problem is to find the minimum enforcer
    salary that would discourage malfeasance
    (at each moment in time)

14
  • We start from the final period (n) of the career
    of a given enforcer
  • At that time, he can receive with
    certainty or, if he engages in malfeasance,
    assuming he is risk neutral, he considers
    expected income with probability
    and with probability p (dismissal). We
    can therefore compute

  • (1)
  • as the minimum wage that discourages malfeasance
  • From the point of view of period , we
    have
  • Substituting (1) in the above expression, we
    find , which can be generalized
    (continuing the backward process) to the other
    periods as

  • for

15
  • The income as an enforcer in the first
    periods is higher than in the outside opportunity
    by an amount that is
  • negatively related to the probability of
    detection
  • positively related to the gain from malfeasance
  • The excess of income in the last period can be
    thought as a pension, stemming from the
    increasing attractiveness of malfeasance as the
    enforcer approaches n
  • When the enforcer approaches n, he may afford to
    be riskier in the sense that if dismissed he
    loses a lower future additional income from being
    an enforcer. This pension is then
  • (note that the premium at all periods until
    is equal to foregone interest on this pension,
    )

16
  • Finally, we can write the present value of the
    lifetime income as an enforcer as
  • where would be implemented as
    an entrance fee for the enforcer profession,
    making it equally attractive as the outside
    opportunity, though still free of malfeasance if
    the period-by-period wages characterized above
    were to be implemented
  • This would be the optimal contract for an
    enforcer so that malfeasance or corruption would
    not arise
  • This assumes imperfect observation from the
    wage-giver, the principal (given probability of
    detection)
  • Therefore, although not explicitly writing about
    it, Becker and Stigler were already tackling what
    was later labeled as an agency problem

17
  • We now relate corruption with the level of
    competition in the provision of the government
    good. This is due to Shleifer and Vishny (QJE,
    1993)
  • We consider a simple model of one
    government-produced good like a passport
  • We assume this good is homogeneous and that
    there is a demand for this good from
    the private agents
  • Let the official government price for this good
    be p
  • We assume this good is sold by an official, who
    represents the government and can refuse to
    provide the good
  • We assume the government official does not face
    any risk of detection/punishment
  • for simplicity, he does not bear any cost from
    producing the good

18
  • Two cases
  • Corruption without theft, where the official
    turns over the official price to the government
    (i.e. p is the marginal cost for the official in
    this case)
  • Corruption with theft, where the official hides
    the sale to the government and keeps all he
    receives for it (i.e. zero marginal cost to the
    official)

19
  • We now consider an extension of this setting to
    allow for private agents in need of several
    complementary government goods
  • Formally consider first a joint monopolist
    agency (collusion) that sets the prices (gross of
    bribes) and of two government goods
  • Let and be the quantities of these goods
    sold, and the official prices be denoted by
    and
  • (per unit bribes can be written as
    and )
  • The joint monopolist agency sets (analysis
    for is symmetric) from
  • where and are marginal revenues
    from the sale of goods 1 and 2
  • When the two goods are complementary we have
    , which means
  • (i.e. a lower bribe on 1 aimed at increasing
    profits on 2).

20
  • Suppose alternatively that permits 1 and 2 are
    allocated by independent agencies. Since each
    agent takes the others actions as given, at the
    independent agencys optimum
    ,
  • This means that under independent sale, the per
    unit bribe is higher and the output lower than at
    the joint monopolist optimum
  • Under a third alternative, each one of the
    several complementary government goods can be
    supplied by at least two government bodies
  • This means that if an official asks for a bribe,
    the possibility of having a lower bribe exists
    with another official
  • This drives bribes down to zero at the
    equilibrium (just like in Bertrand competition)
  • We can then conclude that the level of the bribe
    will be lowest with competition, intermediate
    with collusion among officials, and highest with
    independent monopolistic sales
  • Competition in the provision of government goods
    is therefore key to contain corruption

21
3 Macro Empirical Research
  • Measuring corruption at the macro-level
  • Compilation of country-level indices of
    corruption from middle nineties has brought an
    enormous degree of attention towards
    cross-country studies on the causes and
    consequences of corruption in the 90s/early 2000s
  • Today there are mainly two institutions
    publishing annual country indicators of
    corruption Transparency International (from
    1995) and the World Bank Institute (from 1996)
  • These indices are aggregations of indices from
    multiple sources, involving field in-country
    surveys and international organizations internal
    (expert) polls

22
  • Consequences of corruption
  • Main reference Mauro (QJE, 1995)
  • First paper providing evidence of a negative
    impact of corruption on economic growth, through
    a negative effect on investment
  • Since institutions and economic growth may be
    thought to evolve jointly
  • Use of an index of ethnolinguistic
    fractionalization ELF (measuring the probability
    that two persons drawn randomly from a countrys
    population will not belong to the same
    ethnolinguistic group) as an instrumental
    variable
  • ELF is highly correlated with corruption and
    other institutional variables
  • Think of Shleifer and Vishnys comparison of
    collusive public agencies and independent sale
  • ELF can be assumed exogenous to economic
    variables (that not through institutional
    variables)

23
4 Micro Empirical Research
24
Validity of Macro Indices
  • Fisman and Miguel (JPE, 2006)
  • These authors develop an empirical approach for
    evaluating the role of both social norms and
    legal enforcement in corruption by studying
    parking violations among United Nations diplomats
    living in New York
  • Natural Experiment mission personnel and their
    families benefit from diplomatic immunity, a
    privilege that allowed them to avoid paying
    parking fines prior to Nov. 2002
  • All else constant diplomats/same demographic
    profile same location (close to the UN building)

25
  • Fisman and Miguels results
  • parking violation corruption measure is strongly
    positively correlated with other (survey-based)
    country corruption measures and that this
    relationship is robust to conditioning on region
    fixed effects, country income, and a wide range
    of other controls, including government employee
    salary measures
  • This suggests that home country corruption norms
    are an important predictor of propensity to
    behave corruptly among diplomats
  • by exploiting the increase in the legal
    punishment for parking violations after Nov 2002,
    enforcement matters too it led to immediate and
    massive declines of approximately 98 percent in
    parking violations
  • evidence in favor of convergence to
    zero-enforcement with tenure in New York

26
(No Transcript)
27
(No Transcript)
28
Measurement
  • Reinikka and Svensson (QJE, 2004)
  • describe and analyze the results of a survey
    tool to track the flow of public resources to
    intended destinations (Public Expenditure Track
    Survey)
  • focus on a large public educational program in
    Uganda - a capitation grant to cover schools
    nonwage expenditures - financed and run by the
    central government, using district offices as
    distribution channels
  • comparison of disbursed flows from the central
    government (intended resources) with the
    resources actually received by schools
  • 250 primary schools were surveyed, and data on
    receipts were collected for 19911995
  • Unique panel data set to study the level and
    determinants of local capture

29
  • Reinikka and Svenssons results
  • on average, schools received only 13 percent of
    central government spending on the program most
    schools received nothing the bulk of the grants
    was captured by local government officials (and
    politicians)
  • large variation in grants received across
    schools actual spending, unlike budget
    allocations, is regressive, as schools in
    better-off communities experience a lower degree
    of capture
  • suggestive of a bargaining model between schools
    and local officials
  • the poor seem to be harmed by corruption

30
(No Transcript)
31
(No Transcript)
32
Incentives
  • Olken (JPE, 2006) addresses
  • the relative effectiveness of different types of
    incentives on diminishing corruption
  • top-down based on employer-created monitoring
  • bottom-up based on accountability towards the
    public
  • while using direct measures of corruption (not
    relying on subjective/perception-based data)
  • More specifically, Olken studies a number of
    Indonesian villages where a World Bank-financed
    road project was implemented
  • Corruption is measured by having samples of
    roads constructed under the project evaluated
    independently by engineers and compared with
    reported expenses
  • Research Questions
  • How does corruption respond to an exogenous
    change in the likelihood of government-induced
    audits?
  • How does it respond to a change in the level of
    demand for accountability by villagers?

33
(No Transcript)
34
  • Olkens results
  • Increase probability of an audit (from 4 to
    100) resulted into substantial reductions in
    corruption (8)
  • Both in over-invoicing of labor and un-accounted
    for materials
  • But jobs given to family members increased
  • Both public accountability interventions implied
    small decreases in corruption
  • However, they did imply differential movements
    in the mechanisms of corruption invitations
    alone decreased labor-hidden corruption

35
(No Transcript)
36
Efficiency
  • Bertrand et al (QJE, 2006) address the issue of
    whether corruption is efficient or not (back to
    our first model in the lecture)
  • Back to the analysis of the consequences of
    corruption, at the micro level of Mauro (1995).
  • Bertrand et al follow a sample of applicants
    through the process of obtaining a drivers
    license in New Delhi (India)
  • In the end surprise independent driving tests
    were submitted to all participants this was key
    for the derivation of welfare consequences of
    corruption
  • Main Research Questions
  • Can corruption be used to speed up the process
    of getting a license (grease the wheels)?
  • Do bad drivers use bribes to get a license
    (efficiency question)?

37
(No Transcript)
38
  • Bertrand et als results
  • Apart from confirming a high level of corruption
    (participants paid on average more than twice the
    official fees to obtain their driving license),
    it was found that individuals who wanted to get a
    license faster did so (grease the wheels
    confirmed).
  • Corruption also allowed the circumvention of
    socially useful rules (inefficiency)
  • 69 of the bonus group failed the independent
    driving test (61 in the control group)
  • Being a good driver (lesson group) barely
    increased the likelihood of obtaining a license

39
(No Transcript)
40
Value of Political Connections
  • Fisman (AER, 2001)
  • This author looks at the case of Suhartos
    Indonesia
  • Natural experiment
  • An event study is conducted on a string of
    rumors about former Indonesian President
    Suhartos health during his final years in office
  • Comparison of the returns of firms with
    differing degrees of political exposure

41
  • Fismans results
  • In every case the returns of shares of
    politically dependent firms were considerably
    lower than the returns of less-dependent firms
  • Furthermore, the magnitude of this differential
    effect is highly correlated with the net return
    on the Jakarta Stock Exchange Composite Index
    (JCI) over the corresponding episode
  • In a pooled regression using all the events,
    allowing for an interaction between political
    dependency and event severity, the coefficient
    on this interaction term is positive and
    statistically significant, implying that
    well-connected firms will suffer more, relative
    to less-connected firms, in reaction to a more
    serious rumor
  • Suggest that a large percentage of a
    well-connected firms value may be derived from
    political connections

42
(No Transcript)
43
IO
  • Barron and Olken (2007)
  • Examine the degree to which standard pricing
    theories from industrial organization are
    consistent with actual patterns of bribes and
    extortion payments
  • Context bribes paid by truck drivers on their
    trips to and from the Indonesian province of Aceh
  • Truck drivers in Aceh make a variety of illegal
    payments, including payments to police and
    military officers to avoid harassment at
    checkpoints along the roads, payments at weigh
    stations to avoid fines for driving overweight,
    and protection payments to criminal organizations
    and the police.
  • Measurement enumerators accompanied truck
    drivers along their regular routes to and from
    Aceh
  • From Nov 2005 to Jul 2006, 304 trips to and from
    Aceh, with more than 6,000 illegal payments
    directly observed along the routes

44
  • Barron and Olkens results
  • On average, drivers spent about US 40 per trip,
    or about 13 percent of the total cost of a trip,
    on bribes, extortion, and protection payments
  • During the period of the survey, a major
    withdrawal of government military happened in
    Aceh
  • the average bribe paid in North Sumatra
    increased significantly in response to the
    reduction in the number of checkpoints in Aceh
    (market structure matters)
  • Downstream checkpoints i.e., those that are
    closest to the final destination receive higher
    bribes than upstream checkpoints i.e., those
    that are closer to the origin of the trip
    (hold-up)
  • Officials at checkpoints, for example, appear to
    practice third-degree price discrimination,
    charging higher prices to those drivers with
    observable characteristics that indicate a higher
    willingness to pay (e.g. newer trucks)

45
(No Transcript)
46
Causes A Natural Experiment for the Resource
Curse
  • Vicente (2007 JDE, 2009) looks at an oil
    discovery-induced natural experiment (where the
    source of exogenous variation occurs naturally)
  • This enables analyzing, for a country (Sao Tome
    and Principe STP, West Africa) that departs from
    being resource-free and from having weak
    institutions, how the resource curse may begin
    and evolve
  • Cape Verde, control group
  • The theoretical mechanism proposed is the elite
    wants to increase corruption primarily in
    allocations that enable increasing the likelihood
    of being in power when the oil revenues arrive
  • Research Questions
  • Do natural resources cause corruption?
  • Which are the sectors/allocations by which the
    discovery-induced flow of increased corruption
    begins?

47
(No Transcript)
48
(No Transcript)
49
  • Specifications
  • Difference-in-Difference
  • Triple-difference

50
  • Vicentes results
  • Generalized increase in perceived corruption
    (ranging from 31 to 40 of the subjective scale
    used)
  • Highest and most significant effects on vote
    buying, scholarships for higher education (with
    clear implications in future holding of state
    power) and customs (consumption)
  • Perceptions capture well the sign of the changes
    but exaggerate magnitudes

51
(No Transcript)
52
(No Transcript)
53
5 Summary
  • Corruption vs. Rent-seeking the first not
    assuming inefficiency and closer to empirics the
    second better founded theoretically
  • Incentives crucial to contain corruption
  • Corruption as a competition problem
  • Cross-country indices are not too bad but
    measurement is fundamental (missing value is
    probably the best way to go)
  • Top-down corruption vs. bottom-up some answers
    but some questions remain
  • Corruption greases the wheels but is socially
    inefficient
  • Natural experiments on corruption politically
    connectedness and the effect of oil
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com