- PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Description:

(Traditional) direct referral/placement into job vacancies ... job-search requirements and monitoring. job-search training. direct referrals to job vacancies ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:41
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 24
Provided by: oecd64
Category:
Tags:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title:


1
What works among active labour market policies
  • David Grubb
  • Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social
    Affairs, OECD
  • February 2007

2
Outline
  • Benefits without active measures increase
    unemployment, especially if replacement rates are
    high. Effective active measures reduce
    unemployment. Both types of impact can be large.
  • Classic active measures include labour market
    information and ALMPs (training, job creation and
    hiring subsidies).
  • Activation measures include
  • (Traditional) direct referral/placement into job
    vacancies
  • Other PES interventions in the unemployment
    spell
  • Compulsory participation in ALMPs
    (workfare/trainingfare)
  • Focus on the limits encountered by high-benefit
    countries
  • A few slides consider employment rate outcomes

3
The impact of benefits
  • Simple hazard rate graphs show that limits on UI
    duration considerably affect behaviour (Chart).
  • When UI duration is 14 months the hazard rate
    increases throughout months 10-16? search
    frictions are significant. But employable people
    can usually find work within 6 months.
  • Similar spikes are found in studies from other
    countries.

4
Monthly rate of entry to employment when the
duration of UI benefit was 14 months, France
For four levels of earnings prior to unemployment
Source Dormont et al, as cited by OECD
Employment Outlook 2005
5
The impact of benefits (2)
  • Better-quality studies of the impact of
    replacement rates suggest a fairly large
    elasticity of job entry rates rates with respect
    to replacement rates, e.g. -0.7. But such a
    number is only part of the story
  • Benefits influence rates of entry to
    unemployment, as well as rates of exit
  • Studies estimate short-run impacts, holding
    institutions and social attitudes to unemployment
    near-constant
  • Caseload growth for new (i.e. much more generous)
    assistance benefits has typically continued for
    15 to 20 years (e.g. see OECD, 2003). The
    long-run impact is often around 3 times the
    short-run impact, as judged by caseloads after 20
    years vs. the first few years.

6
History of UI systems and active measures
  • Finland (1971), Luxembourg (1976), Sweden (1974)
    and Switzerland (1976) introduced their current
    (much more generous) unemployment insurance (UI)
    benefits late. They suffered sharp increases in
    unemployment late, in the 1990s i.e. again
    caseload growth took about 20 years. (Chart).
  • Finland and Sweden spent heavily on active labour
    market programmes (ALMPs) before the 1990s, but
    in itself that didnt help.
  • The modern activation strategies were often
    adopted when other measures had been tried but
    unemployment was high or still rising.

7
Unemployment in four countries which introduced
generous unemployment benefits after 1970
other Western Europe
Finland, Sweden
Switzerland, Luxembourg
8
The direct impact of ALMPs
  • Evaluations have identified modest direct impacts
    (impacts on employment-related outcomes of
    participants) from ALMPs. Perhaps slightly
    positive for training programmes, none or even
    negative for job creation. Impacts tend to be
    more positive for adult women than for youth or
    adult men.
  • Training programmes sometimes do better when
    outcomes are tracked over a longer period ? but
    scope for large-scale implementation of
    specialised training remains limited
  • Hiring subsidies are often found effective by
    evaluations using non-experimental (matching)
    estimators ? but other studies continue to show
    deadweight effects (Boockmann et al., 2007).
  • Job-search assistance programmes are often found
    to be relatively effective in relation to their
    low cost.
  • Reference Martin and Grubb (2001).

9
Indirect effects of ALMPs
  • ALMPs can have a large impact through their
    interaction with the benefit system
  • Carousel effects when ALMPs re-qualify
    participants for unemployment benefits.
  • Motivation effects when participation in ALMPs
    is compulsory for long-term benefit recipients.
  • Some channels of impact are rarely identified
    statistically
  • A general change in expectations that affects
    most labour market groups and unemployment
    durations.
  • Impact on rates of (re)entry to unemployment
  • Social interaction effects, i.e. impacts on the
    behaviour of the non-participants in the
    programme.
  • Reference OECD Employment Outlook 2005

10
Activation through regular interventions in the
unemployment spell
  • In Australia, the UK and the US (Welfare Reform)
    activation strategies rely on regular
    interventions" in the unemployment spell
  • personal contact with jobseekers
  • intensive interviews and individual action plans
  • job-search requirements and monitoring
  • job-search training
  • direct referrals to job vacancies
  • sanctions
  • ? These strategies limit benefit caseloads, with
    only a small proportion of the unemployed being
    referred to expensive (full-time) programmes.

11
Activation through participation in labour market
programmes
  • In Denmark, Finland and Sweden activation often
    involves referral to a full-time ALMP. In
    Denmarks active period (in the strategy as of
    about 2000) after a year the unemployed person
    had to participate in an ALMP 75 of the time.
  • Germany and the Netherlands also spend heavily on
    ALMPs.

12
The limits of activation strategies
  • Australia and the UK have moderate benefit
    replacement rates (net 50 to 65 over a
    five-year spell of unemployment) (Chart). They
    spend about 1 of GDP on LMPs (0.4 of GDP for
    active programmes).
  • Austria and Norway have intermediate replacement
    rates. So far they managed to avoid a major
    unemployment crisis and keep spending on LMPs at
    about 2 of GDP.
  • The seven OECD countries (Denmark, Finland,
    Germany, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden,
    Switzerland) with the highest replacement rates
    (75 or more over a five over a five-year spell
    of unemployment in 2002, 2004 data) find it
    relatively difficult and expensive to get good
    results.

13
Average of net replacement rates over 60 months
of unemployment, including social assistance
2004, for four family types and two earnings
levels, in percentage
14
In the high-benefit countries
  • High spending on ALMPs (e.g. Sweden, Finland
    before 1990 and Germany in the 1990s) did not
    prevent unemployment from rising further, to
    postwar peak levels.
  • Total LMP spending is very high in several cases
    (3.0-4.5 of GDP in Denmark, Finland, Germany and
    the Netherlands).
  • A large immigrant-native differential in
    unemployment and employment rates (Chart) is
    proving hard to tackle.
  • Strict workfare/trainingfare" requirements seem
    to be needed for the management of social
    assistance (Kildal, 2000 Thoren, 2005, describes
    some Swedish schemes).
  • Experimentation continues, e.g. privatisation of
    employment services in Denmark, the Activity
    Guarantee" in Sweden, and controversial benefit
    cuts.

15
Unemployment rates of non-EU immigrants vs.
natives
Source Jean (2006)
16
Avoiding programme dependency
  • When referral to ALMPs is a key element in an
    activation strategy, one issue is how to avoid
    programme dependency - when some unemployed
    people prefer ALMPs (rather than passive
    benefits) to market work.
  • Employer demand for subsidies should not be
    allowed to drive growth in ALMPs.
  • Subsidised employment positions should pay less
    than market work.
  • Potential programme careers should be
    interrupted by short intervals in open
    unemployment with a focus on job search and
    renegotiation of the individual action plan, as
    in Denmark.

17
Improve PES performance
  • The Public Employment Service (PES) implements
    regular interventions, so this type of
    activation strategy depends on PES performance.
  • The PES may tend to limit itself to bureaucratic
    routines and intermediation (matching willing
    workers with employers).
  • An ineffective PES may remain so for long
    periods, since clear evidence of poor performance
    is absent.
  • The biggest policy reforms have often involved
    not only legislation but also PES restructuring -
    new financing arrangements, new objectives, new
    management.

18
Performance management
  • Structure PES operations to
  • Measure the performance of different employment
    offices in terms of entries to employment (of
    minimum duration, at least 3 months) achieved by
    their clients.
  • Compare employment outcomes across employment
    offices, and reform underperforming operations
  • A quasi-market or subcontracting approach, where
    regular interventions are implemented by
    provide providers works well in Australia and
    arguably also in the UK (Employment Zone
    providers are benchmarked against outcomes
    achieved by the PES with comparable client
    groups).
  • Performance measurement in the PES has some
    (perhaps more limited) impact even without
    subcontracting.
  • Reference OECD Employment Outlook 2005

19
Activation of "non-employment" benefits
  • Non-employment benefits are those paid without
    an availability-for-work condition. Activation
    may involve
  • Specific measures, e.g. employer financial
    responsibility for their employees sickness pay,
    work rehabilitation measures for medical
    conditions, child care provision for lone
    parents
  • Abolition (e.g. phasing out an early retirement
    benefit) or stricter gatekeeping (e.g. for
    disability benefits). Some potential
    beneficiaries then claim unemployment benefit
    instead.
  • Introduction of an availability-for-work
    condition (e.g. for lone parents with children
    above a certain age, partners in a couple
    receiving a minimum income benefit, some groups
    in receipt of a disability benefit).
  • Reference Carcillo and Grubb (2006)

20
Low unemployment as a precondition
  • The PES is effective when most benefit spells are
    kept shorter than 6 months.
  • If benefit spells become longer, job-search
    motivation is difficult to maintain and the
    potential disincentive effects of high benefits
    act more strongly.
  • Success in managing the pre-existing unemployed
    caseload is a precondition for activation of
    non-employment benefits by adding an
    availability-for-work condition.
  • If the PES is overwhelmed by a transfer of new
    hard-to-place clients, the net effect may be
    negative.

21
Employment rates
  • Small variations in unemployment rates are
    associated with larger variations in labour force
    participation rates (Chart). ? Policies which
    keep unemployment low also (a) attract potential
    workers into the labour force (b) facilitate
    restrictive management of non-employment
    benefits.
  • For certain outliers such as Belgium (with a
    60 employment rate, far below 72 in Canada
    which has a similar unemployment rate),
    non-employment benefits (e.g. early retirement
    benefits) are a factor.
  • Evidence about other factors influencing
    employment rates is relatively uncertain. Two
    suspects are employment protection (EPL) (? low
    employment rate) and progressive taxation of
    individual incomes (? high employment rate).

22
Employment and unemployment rates, 2000-5
23
References
  • Boockmann, B., T. Zwick, A. Ammermüller and M.
    Maier (2007), Do Hiring Subsidies Reduce
    Unemployment Among the Elderly? Evidence From Two
    Natural Experiments, ZEW Discussion Paper no.
    07-001
  • Carcillo, S. and D. Grubb (2006), From
    Inactivity to Work The Role of Active Labour
    Market Policies, SEM Working Paper no. 36
    (www.oecd.org/els/workingpapers).
  • Dormont, B., D. Fougère and A. Prieto (2001),
    Leffet de lallocation unique dégressive sur la
    reprise demploi, Économie et Statistique, No.
    343, pp. 3-28
  • Graversen, B. and J. van Ours (2006), How to
    Help Unemployed Find Jobs Quickly Experimental
    Evidence from a Mandatory Activation Program,
    IZA DP no. 2504.
  • Kildal, N. (2000), Workfare Tendencies in
    Scandinavian Welfare Policies, ILO.
  • Grubb, D. (2005), Trends in Unemployment
    Insurance, Related Benefits and Active Labour
    Market Policies in Europe 10th Anniversary of EI
    seminar (www.kli.re.kr)
  • Jean, S. (2006), The Labour Market Integration
    of Immigrants in OECD Countries,
    (www.oecd.org/document/47/0,2340,en_2649_37415_367
    21391_1_1_1_37415,00.html).
  • Martin, J. and D. Grubb (2001), What works and
    for whom A review of OECD countriesexperiences
    with active labour market policies, Swedish
    Economic Policy Review 8, pp.9-56.
  • OECD (2003), Benefits and Employment, Friend or
    Foe? Interactions Between Passive and Active
    Social Programmes, Employment Outlook, Paris.
  • OECD (2005), Labour Market Programmes and
    Activation Strategies Evaluating the Impacts
    and Public Employment Services Managing
    Performance, Employment Outlook, Paris
  • OECD (2006), Employment Outlook Boosting Jobs
    and Incomes, Paris.
  • Thoren, K. (2005), Municipal activation policy
    A case study of the practical work with
    unemployed social assistance recipients, IFAU
    working paper 200520.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com