Title: Materials for Lecture 14
1Materials for Lecture 14
- Watch an episode of Deal or No Deal
- Read Chapter 10
- Read Chapter 16 Section 11.0
- Lecture 15 CEs.xls
- Lecture 15 Elicit Utility.xls
- Lecture 15 Ranking Scenarios.xls
- Lecture 15 Ranking Scenarios Whole Farm.xls
- Lecture 15 Utility Function.xls
2Ranking Risky Alternatives
- After simulating multiple scenarios your job is
to help the decision maker pick the best
alternative - Two ways to approach this problem
- Positive economics role of economist is to
present consequences and not make recommendations - Normative economics role of economist is to
make recommendations - Simulation results can be presented many
different ways to help the decision maker (DM)
make the best decision for him/herself - Purpose of this lecture is to present the best
methods for ranking risky alternatives so the DM
can make the best decision
3Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Decision makers rank risky alternatives based on
their utility for income and risk - Several of the ranking procedures ignore utility,
but they are easy to use - The more complex procedures incorporate utility
but can be complicated to use
4Easy to Use Ranking Procedures
- Mean only Pick scenario with the highest mean
-- throw away the risk
- Minimize Risk Pick the scenario with lowest
Std Dev this ranking strategy ignores the
level of returns (mean and relative risk)
- Mean Variance often difficult to read, does
not work well for non-normal distributions.
Always select the scenario in lower right
quadrant.
- From diagram below A is preferred to C E is
preferred to B
(income)
5Easy to Use Ranking Procedures
- Worst case ignores the level of returns but
has merit in that it avoids catastrophic
losses, ignores upside risk. Bases decisions on
scenario with highest minimum, but it observed
with a 1 chance. Worst case had a 1 out of
500 chance of being observed.
- Best case ignores the overall risk and
downside potential risk. Looks at only one
iteration, the best, with a 1 chance. Worst case
had a 1 out of 500 chance of being observed.
0
6Easy to Use Ranking Procedures
- Relative Risk Coefficient of Variation (CV),
pick the scenario that has lowest absolute CV.
Easy to use, considers risk relative to the level
of returns but ignores the decision makers risk
aversion.
7Easy to Use Ranking Procedures
- Probabilities of Target Values Calculate and
report the probability of achieving a preferred
target and probability of failing to achieve a
minimum target, i.e., the StopLight chart. This
method is easy to use and easy to present to
decision makers who do not understand risk.
8Easy to Use to Rank Procedures
- Rank Scenarios Based on Complete Distribution
Graph the distributions as CDFs and compare the
relative risk of the returns for each
distribution at alternative levels of return.
Pick the distribution with the most return for
each risk level or pick the distribution with the
lowest risk for each level of returns, i.e., the
distribution further to the right.
9Utility Based Risk Ranking Procedures
- Utility and risk are often stated as a lottery
- Assume you own a lottery ticket that will pay you
10 or 0, each with a probability of 50 - Risk neutral DM will sell the ticket for 5
- Risk averse DM will sell ticket for a certain
(non-risky) payment less than 5, say 4 - Risk loving DM will sell if paid a certain amount
greater than 5, say 7 - Amount of the certain payment to part with the
ticket is DMs Certainty Equivalent or CE - Risk premium (RP) is the difference between the
CE and the expected value - RP E(value) CE
- RP 5 4
10Utility Based Risk Ranking Procedures
- CE is used everyday when we make risky decisions
- We implicitly calculate a CE for each risky
alternative - Deal or No Deal game show is a good example
- Player has 4 unopened boxes with amounts of
- 5, 50,000, 250,000 and 0
- Host offers a certain payment (say, 65,000) NOT
to open another box and exit the game, the
certain payment is always less than the expected
value (E(x) 75,001.25 in this example) - If a contestant takes the Deal, then the Certain
Payment offer exceeded their CE for that
particular gamble
11Ranking Risky Alternatives Using Utility
- With a simple assumption, the DM prefers more to
less, then we can rank risky alternatives with
CE - DM will prefer the risky alternative with the
greatest CE - To calculate a CE, all we have to do is assume
a utility function and that the DM is rational
and consistent, calculate their risk aversion
function, and then calculate the DMs utility for
a risky choice
12Ranking Risky Alternatives Using Utility
- Utility based risk ranking tools in Simetar
- Stochastic dominance with respect to a function
(SDRF) - Certainty equivalents (CE)
- Stochastic efficiency with respect to a function
(SERF) - Risk Premiums (RP)
- All of these procedures require estimating the
DMs risk aversion coefficient (RAC) as it is the
parameter for the Utility Function -
13Suggestions on Setting the RACs
- Anderson and Dillon (1992) proposed a RAC
definition of - 0.0 risk neutral
- 0.5 hardly risk averse
- 1.0 normal or somewhat risk averse
- 2.0 moderately risk averse
- 3.0 very risk averse
- 4.0 extremely risk averse (4.01 is a maximum)
- Rule for setting RRAC and ARAC range is
- Relative RACs of 0 to 4.001 for the Power
utility function - Absolute RACs of 0 to 4/Wealth for the
Negative Exponential utility function
14Assuming a Utility Function for the DM
- Power utility function
- Use this function when assuming the DM exhibits
evidence of relative risk aversion - DM willing to take on more risk as wealth
increases - Or when ranking risky scenarios with a KOV that
is summarized over multiple years, as - Net Present Value (NPV)
- Present Value of Ending Net Worth (PVENW)
- Negative Exponential utility function
- Use this function when assuming DM exhibits
constant absolute relative risk aversion - DM does not take on more risk as income increases
- Or when ranking risky scenarios using KOVs for
single years, such as - Annual net cash income or return on investments
15Estimate the DMs RAC
- Calculate RAC
- Enter values in the cells that are Yellow
- Lecture 15 Elicit Utility .xls
16Stochastic Dominance
- Stochastic Dominance assumes
- Decision maker is an expected value maximizer
- Alternative distributions (F and G) are mutually
exclusive - Distributions F and G are based on population
probability distributions. In simulation, these
are 500 iterations for alternative scenarios of a
KOV, e.g. NPV - First degree dominance when CDFs do not cross.
- In this case we can say, All decision makers
prefer distribution furthest to the right. - However, we are not always lucky enough to have
distributions that do not cross.
17Stochastic Dominance wrt a Function (SDRF)
- Generalized SDRF measures the difference between
two risky distributions, F and G, at each value
on the Y axis, and weights differences by a
utility function using the DMs ARAC.
1.0
- F(x) dominates G(x) for NPV values from zero to A
and G(x) dominates from A to B, F(x) dominates
for NPV values B - At each probability, calculate F(x) minus G(x)
(the horizontal bars between F and G) and weight
the difference by a utility function for the
upper and lower RACs - Sum the differences and keep score of U(F(x))
U(G(x))
18Ranking Scenarios with SDRF in Simetar
- Interpretation of a sample Stochastic Dominance
result
- For all decision makers with a RAC of -0.01 to
0.1 - The preferred scenarios are Options 1 and 2 the
efficient set - If Options 1 and 2 are not available, then Option
3 is preferred - Options 4 and 5 are the least preferred
- Note that Stochastic Dominance resulted in a
split decision - The Efficient Set has more than one alternative
19Rank Risky Scenarios Using CE
Lecture 15
20Ranking Scenarios with Stochastic Efficiency
(SERF)
- Stochastic Efficiency with Respect to a Function
(SERF) calculates the certainty equivalent for
risky alternatives at 25 different RAC levels - Compare CE of all risky alternatives at each RAC
level - Scenario with the highest CE at the DMs RAC is
the preferred scenario - Summarize the CE results for possible RACs in a
chart - Identify the efficient set based on the highest
CE within a range of RACs - Efficient Set
- This is utility shorthand for saying the risky
alternative(s) that is (are) the most preferred
21Ranking Scenarios with Stochastic Efficiency
(SERF)
- SERF requires an assumption about the decision
makers utility function and like SDRF uses a
range of RACs - SERF ranks risky strategies based on expected
utility which is expressed as CE - Simetar includes SERF and calculates a table of
CEs over a range of RAC values from the LRAC to
the URAC and develops a chart for ranking
alternatives
22SERF Table of CE Values
- In this example the RAC range of 0.0005 to
0.0005 is specified and 25 separate RACs are
calculated and used over this range - The RACs can be changed dynamically and the CE
values are re-calculated by Simetar - The CEs for each of the 5 scenarios are
calculated for each of the 25 RAC values, given
the Utility function - Read across the table to find which scenario is
best at each RAC it has the highest CE at each
RAC level
23Ranking Scenarios with SERF
- The SERF Table points out the reason that SDRF
produces inconsistent rankings - SDRF only uses the minimum and maximum RACs
- The efficient set (ranking) can differ from
minimum the RAC to the maximum RAC - Changing the RACs and re-running SDRF can be slow
- The SERF Table can show the actual RAC where the
decision maker is indifferent between scenarios
(this is the BRAC or breakeven risk aversion
coefficient) - The SERF Table is best understood as a chart
developed by Simetar
24Ranking Scenarios with SERF
- Two examples are presented next
- The first is for ranking an annual decision using
annual net cash income - Uses negative exponential utility function
- Lower ARAC zero
- Upper ARAC 4.0/Wealth
- The second example is for ranking a multiple year
decision using NPV variable - Uses Power Utility function
- Lower RRAC zero
- Upper RRAC 4.001
25Ranking Risky Annual NCIs with SERF
26Ranking Risky Annual NCIs with SERF
27Ranking Risky Alternative NPVs with SERF
28Ranking Risky Alternatives with SERF
- Interpret the SERF chart as follows
- The risky alternative that has the highest CE at
a particular RAC is the preferred strategy - Within a range of RACs the risky alternative
which has the highest CE line is preferred - If the CE lines cross at that point the DM is
indifferent between the two risky alternatives - If the CE line goes negative, the DM would rather
earn nothing than to invest in that alternative - Interpret the rankings within risk aversion
intervals - RAC 0 is for risk neutral DMs
- RAC 1 or 1/W is for normal slightly risk
aversion DMs - RAC 2 or 2/W is for moderately risk averse DMs
- RAC 4 or 4/W is for extremely risk averse DMs
29Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Advanced materials provided as an appendix
- The following overheads are to good to trash but
make the lecture to long - They complement the data in Chapter 10
30Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Xrandom income simulated for Alter 1
- Yrandom income simulated for Alter 2
- Level of income realized for either is x or y
- If risk neutral, prefer Alter 1 if E(X) E(Y)
- In terms of utility theory, prefer Alter 1 iff
- E(U(X)) E(U(Y))
- Given that expected utility is calculated as
- E(U(X)) ? P(Xx) U(x) for all levels x
- where P(Xx) is probability income equals x
31Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Each risky alternative has a unique CE once we
have assumed a utility function or U(CE)
E(U(X)) - Constant risk aversion (CRA) means that if we add
1 to each outcome we do not change the ranking - If a bet pays 10 or 0 with probability of 50
it may have a CE of 4 - Then if a bet pays 11 or 0 with Probability of
50 the CE is greater than 4 - CRA is a reasonable assumption and it allows us
to demonstrate risk ranking
32Ranking Risky Alternatives
- A CRA simple utility function is the negative
exponential function - U(x) A - EXP(-x r)
- A is a constant to convert income to positives
- r is the ARAC or absolute risk aversion
coefficient - x is the realized income for the alternative
- EXP is the exponent function in Excel
- We can estimate the decision makers RAC by
asking a series of questions regarding gambles
33Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Calculate Utility for a random return or income
given a RAC - U(x) A EXP(- (xscalar) r)
- Let A 1000 to scale all utility values to
positive - Can try different RAC values such as 0.001
Lecture 15
34Alternative RACs
Lecture 15
35Add or Subtract a Constant Amount
Lecture 15
36Ranking Risky Alternatives
- Three steps in Utility Analysis
- 1st convert the monetary payoffs to utility
values using a utility function as U(X)
A-EXP(-xr) and repeat this step for Y - 2nd calculate the expected value of U(x) as
- E(U(X)) ? P(Xx) A-EXP(-xr)
- Repeat this step for Y
- 3rd convert the E(U(X)) and the E(U(Y))to a CE
- CE(X) CE(Y) means we prefer X to Y based on
the DM ARAC of r and the utility function and the
simulated Y and X values - A short cut is to calculate CE directly for a
decision makers RAC - Simetar includes a function for calculating
- CE CERTEQ(risky income, RAC)
-
37Ranking Risky Alternatives
Lecture 15