Title: The Labour Market Chapter 11
1The Labour MarketChapter 11
- LIPSEY CHRYSTAL
- ECONOMICS 12e
2Learning Outcomes
- Some long-lasting wage differentials arise from
differences in skills and educational
attainments, and some arise from differences in
age and gender. - The full characteristics of many of todays
workers are hard to ascertain in advance, so
labour market practices evolve to cope with
imperfect and asymmetric information.
3Learning Outcomes
- Some wage differentials arise from the type of
market in which labour is sold different wages
are likely to be produced by competitive markets,
where there are many buyers and sellers. - In monopoly markets, in which unions control the
supply, and in markets in which there are so few
employers that each has power to influence the
outcome.
4Learning Outcomes
- Efficiency wages are above the minimum that would
be required to hire a worker as they contain an
incentive for the employee to perform well - Selection and management procedures evolve to
provide effective monitoring and incentive
mechanisms - Internal labour markets within firms are like
tournaments in which employees compete for
promotion to more senior and better paid jobs
5INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Wage Differentials
- Equilibrium wage differentials can arise among
jobs because a each requires different degrees
of physical or mental abilities, b each
requires different amounts of human capital
acquired through costly formal education or
on-the-job training, c some jobs are closed to
people who could fill them as a result of
discrimination, and d the factor markets
related to different jobs have different
competitive structures.
6INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Wage Differentials
- In perfectly competitive factor markets, wages
are set by demand and supply and there is no
unemployment in equilibrium. - In monopolistic markets, wages and employment are
less than their competitive levels, but there is
no unemployment in equilibrium.
7INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- If a union enters a perfectly competitive market,
it can raise wages above the competitive level at
the cost of lowering employment and creating a
pool of persons who would like to work at the
union wage but cannot. - If a union enters a monopsonistic labour market,
it can raise wages and employment to the
competitive level.
8INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- If it raises wages beyond that point, employment
will fall. - Unions and professional associations can
sometimes restrict the supply of labour and
thereby achieve wages above the competitive
equilibrium without creating a pool of
unemployed.
9INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Minimum-wage laws have a similar effect to the
setting of wages by unions. - If the market was monopsonistic before the
minimum wage is imposed, wages and employment can
be raised. - If it was competitive, wages can be raised only
at the expense of some (possibly small) reduction
in employment in the affected occupation.
10INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Heterogeneity, Incentives, and Monitoring Costs
- Todays labour markets are complicated by the
fact that brainpower is extremely heterogeneous
but it is hard for employers to discern the full
characteristics of individual workers. - Many employment contracts are relational
contracts, which do not specify in detail what
workers have to do.
11INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Heterogeneity, Incentives, and Monitoring Costs
- This creates the potential for principal-agent
problems, where the hired employees act, in part,
in their own interest rather than that of the
employer. - Solutions to the principal-agent problem involve
some combination of incentives and monitoring.
12INTRODUCTION - THE LABOUR MARKET
- Most skilled, managerial, and professional
workers now find themselves in an internal labour
market that has some of the characteristics of a
tournament. - Here the main incentive for lower - and
middle-ranking staff is to achieve promotion. - Higher pay generally attaches to more senior
jobs, and the competition to gain promotion can
be thought of as a tournament.
13The costs and benefits of formal education
S
U
Income earned
L T
L
Age
0
Direct cost of education
Net cost of education
Consumer satisfaction
14The costs and benefits of formal education
- Acquiring human capital through formal education
beyond minimum school-leaving age implies costs
now and benefits later. - Age is plotted on the horizontal axis and income
earned on the vertical axis. - Income is zero until age L, which is the minimum
school-leaving age. - After that the yellow line, U, shows the income
of a typical person who leaves school at age L
and takes the relatively unskilled job. - The blue line, S, shows the more complicated
stream of payments and income receipts of someone
who stays on for T years of formal training after
age L. - At first receipts are negative, reflecting the
net out-of -pocket expenses related to attending
school and university.
15The costs and benefits of formal education
- Deducting the consumption value placed on being
at school rather than at work (light yellow area)
yields the net cost associated with being in
school. - Adding this to the income that could have been
earned by going directly into the labour force at
age L yields the total cost of the education,
which is the medium yellow area. - The benefit is shown by the dark yellow area,
representing the difference between the income
earned in the skilled lob that is acquired at
year L T (line S) and the income that would
have been earned if the labour force had been
entered at age L (line U).
16The costs and benefits of formal education
- The investment in human capital could not
possibly be worthwhile unless the dark yellow
benefit area exceeded the medium yellow cost
area. - The net benefit to a particular individual
depends on how much he or she discounts the
future gain in order to compare it with the
immediate costs.
17Economic Discrimination
DE
D0
Wage rate
Wage rate
Quantity of labour
Quantity of labour
i. Elite market E
ii. Ordinary market O
18Economic Discrimination
S0
DE
D0
SE
Wage rate
E0
Wage rate
w0
E0
w0
q1
q0
q0
Quantity of labour
Quantity of labour
i. Elite market E
ii. Ordinary market O
19Economic Discrimination
S0
DE
SE
D0
S0
SE
E1
Wage rate
E0
Wage rate
w1
w0
E0
E1
w0
w2
q1
q0
q2
q0
Quantity of labour
Quantity of labour
i. Elite market E
ii. Ordinary market O
20Economic discrimination, (i) elite market
- Market E requires above-average skills.When there
is no discrimination, demand and supply are DE
and SE. - Initially the wage rate is w0 and employment is
q0. - Now let Y-type workers be barred from E
occupations. - The supply curve shifts to SE and the wage
earned by the remaining workers, all of whom are
type X, rises to w1.
21Economic discrimination, (ii) ordinary market
- Market O requires only ordinary skills. When
there is no discrimination, demands and supplies
are D0 and S0. - Initially the wage rate is w0 and employment is
q0. - Now let type-Y workers be barred from E
occupations. - The Y workers put out of work in the E market
move to the O market, shifting its supply curve
to S0 . - The wage earned by the workers in the O market
falls to w2 . - Because all Ys are forced into the O occupations,
their wage is lower than the wages earned in the
E market.
22Figure 15.4 A Monopsonist Facing Many Sellers
MC
S
Em
wc
Wage rate
wm
D MRP
qm
qc
Quantity of labour
23A monopsonist facing many sellers
- The competitive wage and employment are wc, and
qc. - The monopsonist who must pay the same wage to all
equates the marginal cost of hiring labour with
labours marginal revenue product, which occurs
at point Em. - The firm hires qm workers at a wage of wm,.
Labours income is shown by the dark yellow and
dark blue areas enclosed by qm, and wm. - A perfectly discriminating monopsonist can pay
each worker his or her supply price, so the S
curve is also its marginal cost curve.
24A monopsonist facing many sellers
- The firm will hire qc and pay a total income
equal to the dark and medium blue areas under the
S curve. - The monoponist's profits are the light yellow
area between wm, and wc and the dark yellow area
between wm and the S curve. (Under perfect
competition both yellow areas are parts of
labours income.)
25A Single Union Facing Many Employers
S
D
E1
Wage rate
x
w1
E0
w0
q1
q0
q2
Quantity of labour
26A Single Union Facing Many Employers
- Competitive equilibrium is at E0.
- The union sets the wage at w1.
- This creates a perfectly elastic supply curve of
labour up to the quantity q2 which is the amount
of labour willing to work at the wage w1. - Equilibrium is at E1 with q1 workers employed and
q2 q1 willing to work at the going wage rate
but unable to find employment. Labour income is
shown by the blue area.
27A Single Union Facing a Single Employer
MC
S
wu
x
E0
w0
Wage rate
wm
MRP D
qm
q2
q0
Quantity of Labour
28A Single Union Facing a Single Employer
- The monopsonist facing competitively supplied
labour is in the equilibrium with qm, workers
employed at a wage of wm,. - If a newly entering union sets its wage at w0,
the supply curve runs from w0 to E0 and then
rises along the line S. - Equilibrium is at E0 with employment at q0.
- If the union seeks a wage higher than w0, it must
accept a lower level of employment than q0. - The union can, for example, set a wage at wu,
creating a supply curve that runs from wu to x
then up the S curve.
29A Single Union Facing a Single Employer
- This yields the same level of employment, qm, as
when the monopsonist dominated the market. - But the wage of wu is much higher.
- At that wage rate there are q2 - qm people who
would like to work but who are unable to find
employment.