Lecture 5 Monopoly practice and the competitive limit - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Lecture 5 Monopoly practice and the competitive limit

Description:

Ski resorts (amusement parks, cellular phone companies internet or cable operators) offer vacation packages for ... on the mountain, and ski lift tickets. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:34
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 43
Provided by: vesnapra
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Lecture 5 Monopoly practice and the competitive limit


1
Lecture 5Monopoly practice and the competitive
limit
The latter parts of the lecture analyze other
aspects of monopolistic practices. We discuss
mechanisms for setting prices and quantities, the
role of commitment, market segmentation, and
product bundling. Then we investigate the effects
of competition,the competitive limit and the
related concept of competitive equilibrium.
2
A dynamic inconsistency?
But what if the monopolist set price so that
marginal revenue equals marginal cost, and the
demanders whose valuations exceeded the price
immediately purchased the item at the beginning
of the game?
3
The static solution illustrated
Price in dollars
20
inverse demand curve
Uniform price solution
unit cost
10
marginal revenue curve
quantity
0
Uniform quantity solution
4
Residual demand
Price
New vertical axis for origin of residual inverse
demand
20
Uniform price solution
Unit cost
10
New marginal revenue curve
Quantity
0
5
Will price fall to marginal cost?
  • The solution to this game is for the monopolist
    to let the price decline to where marginal
    revenue equals marginal cost at the end of the
    game, thus presenting each consumer
    simultaneously with a take it or leave it offer
    at that price.
  • Equivalently, the monopolist can commit to a
    uniform price policy by committing to everyone
    the lowest price he offers to anyone.
  • Letting a firm split can also resolve the
    problem if each of the new break off firms
    guarantee to match each others discounts.

6
Durable goods monopoly
  • One way of avoiding the problem associated with
    a random cut-off time is to rent the good for
    short periods.
  • But this is not always possible, and it might
    be desirable to attempt to price discriminate
    between consumers.
  • There are two cases to focus on
  • 1. Constant marginal cost
  • 2. Fixed supply

7
Discriminating monopolist
  • Price and product discrimination is more
    widespread than in durable goods problems, where
    the monopolist may be able to sort customers by
    their urgency.
  • Suppose the monopolist knows the valuations of
    the players, and can commit to prices.
  • Make a take it or leave it offer to each
    person multi person ultimatum game.
  • Now imagine that it cannot prevent players from
    buying in any market they like.
  • Now let monopolist condition on characteristics
    that are related to their valuations which he
    cannot observe.

8
Multiple markets
  • Consider now another related method for
    segmenting market demand to extract greater
    economic rent.
  • The firm exploits the idea that customers who
    demand several of the firms products might
    exhibit more elastic demands (be more price
    sensitive) than customers who only wish to
    purchase a smaller subset of the firms products.
  • Perhaps the most common example of this
    behavior is quantity discounting (sometimes
    enforced through packaging).

9
Other examples
  1. Firms sell assembled goods such as cars or other
    durables for new car buyers and demand from
    previous buyers, plus replacement parts arising
    from collision damage or wear and tear.
  2. Restaurants (furniture stores, car dealers) offer
    complete dinners (suites, high performance and
    luxury packages) with a limited (selected) range
    of items, and also offer portions a la carte (set
    pieces, individual components).
  3. Ski resorts (amusement parks, cellular phone
    companies internet or cable operators) offer
    vacation packages for lodging and tickets (entry
    or connection plus service charges) as well as
    sell tickets (services) by themselves.

10
A product bundling monopolist
  • A resort owner has a monopoly over two
    products, called accommodation on the mountain,
    and ski lift tickets.
  • Some demanders visit the mountain resort to ski
    downhill, while others come to cross country ski
    or snowshoe (neither of which requires lift
    tickets). Demanders also choose between commuting
    from the city 90 minutes by road, or by renting
    an apartments or a hotel room at the resort.
  • What should the resort owner charge for ski
    tickets, for accommodation, and for the holiday
    package of both?

11
The number of rivals
  • Now we investigate how the solution to trading
    games is affected by relaxing the assumption that
    there is only a single supplier (or more
    generally dealer) in each market.
  • First we analyze how monopoly power breaks down
    with competition from rival producers.
  • This leads us to define price taking behavior
    and a definition of competitive equilibrium.

12
The competitive limit
  • We first consider two extensions of the
    multiunit auction, where there is a constant
    marginal cost of production.
  • In the first case we assume that entry occurs
    sequentially until it is unprofitable to do so.
    This corresponds to a competitive market where
    rival suppliers compete for demanders.
  • In the second case we assume that the
    monopolist or cartel maximizes producer surplus.

13
Duopoly
Considering the monopoly problem of the previous
lecture, let us now introduce a second seller
with same marginal cost schedule, and no fixed
costs.
14
Three or more producers
  • Continuing in this vein, one could fragment the
    organization of production even more.
  • For example consider how three or more
    producers would compete against each other.
  • Can we endogenously determine the number of
    entrants?

15
Price competition and capacity constraints
  • It seems that a remarkably small number of
    competing firms suffice to drive the price down
    to marginal cost.
  • But this result is partly driven by the cost
    structure.
  • Now suppose there is a two stage game, where
    firms construct capacity for production in the
    first stage, and market their produce in a second
    stage.

16
Declining marginal cost
Now suppose unit costs fall with scale of
production. For example suppose there is a fixed
cost of entry (technological know how or plant
set up) as well as a constant marginal cost. If
there is only one producer, then the profit
maximizing quantity for the firm is What
happens in the case of two producers?
17
Is there convergence?
  • A natural question to ask is where this process
    would converge, and whether there is an easy way
    to model what would happen in the limit.
  • Do our experiments suggest that the limit point
    depends on the cost structure?
  • Another question is how many firms are required
    to reach this limit (that is when it exists).

18
Free entry
  • Consider first the uniform distribution. In a
    second price auction
  • In the first case we assume that entry occurs
    sequentially until it is unprofitable to do so.
    This corresponds to a competitive market where
    rival suppliers compete for demanders.
  • In the second case we assume that the
    monopolist or cartel maximizes producer surplus.

19
Definition of competitive equilibrium
A competitive equilibrium is a single price, or a
price band (an interval on the real line), with
two defining properties 1. Traders treat each
point in the competitive equilibrium as a fixed
price, seeking to buy or sell units of the good
that maximize their objective function at that
fixed price. 2. At every price above those in
the competitive equilibrium, demand exceeds
supply. At every price below those in the
competitive equilibrium, supply exceeds demand.
20
Competitive equilibrium as a tool for prediction
  • The key advantage from assuming that markets
    are in competitive equilibrium is that models of
    competitive equilibrium are relatively
    straightforward to analyze.
  • For example, deriving the properties of a Nash
    equilibrium solution to a trading game is
    typically more complex than deriving the
    competitive equilibrium for the same game.
  • In other words, using the tools of competitive
    equilibrium we can sometimes make accurate
    predictions with minimal effort.

21
An economy with one stock
  • Consider the following economy
  • There is one stock, as well as money. The
    common value of the asset is constant, and every
    one is fully informed.
  • There are a finite number of player types, say
    I. Every player belonging to a given player type
    has the same asset and money endowment, and the
    same private valuation.
  • Players belonging to type i are distinguished
    by their initial endowment of money mi and the
    stock si, as well as their private valuation of
    the stock vi. Thus a player type i is defined by
    the triplet (mi, si, vi).

22
Example 1
  • To make matters more concrete, suppose there
    are 10 players, with private valuations that take
    on the integer values from 1 to 10.
  • Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
    endowed with 4 units of the good, and everybody
    else has 12 to buy units of the good.
  • We also assume that everyone has the same
    access to the market, and can place limit or
    market orders.

23
The front page of a players folio.
24
Example 2
  • Now we modify the example a little.
  • To make matters more concrete, suppose there are
    10 players, with private valuations that take on
    the integer values from 1 to 10.
  • Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
    endowed with 4 units of the good, and everybody
    else has 12 to buy units of the good.
  • As before we assume that everyone has the same
    access to the market, and can place limit or
    market orders.

25
The front page
26
Using supply and demand curves to derive
competitive equilibrium
  • To derive the competitive equilibrium, compute
    the demand for the asset minus the supply of the
    asset (both as a function of price), otherwise
    known as the net demand for the asset.
  • Then aggregate across players to obtain the
    aggregate net demand.
  • The set of competitive equilibrium prices is
    found by applying the second part of the
    definition every price below (above) prices in
    the set generate positive (negative) aggregate
    net demand.

27
Individual optimization in a competitive
equilibrium
  • In a competitive equilibrium with price p the
    objective of player i is to pick the quantity of
    stock traded, denoted qi, to maximize the value
    of his or her portfolio subject to constraints
    that prevent short sales (selling more stock than
    the the seller holds) or bankruptcy (not having
    enough liquidity to cover purchases).
  • The value of the portfolio of player i is

28
Constraints in the optimization problem
The short sale constraint is
The solvency constraint is
These constraints can be combined as
29
Solution to the individualsoptimization problem
The solution to this linear problem is to
specialize the stock if vi exceeds p, specialize
in money if p exceeds vi, and choose any feasible
quantity q if vi p. That is
and
30
Aggregate demand
  • Summing across the individual demands of players
    we obtain the demand across players curve D(p).
  • Let 1 . . . be an indicator function, taking a
    value of 1 if the statement inside the
    parentheses is true, and 0 if false. Then, the
    demand from those players who wish to increase
    their holding of the stock is
  • Thus D(p) declines in steps, for two reasons.
    As p falls the number of players with valuations
    exceeding p increases, and demanders who are
    willing to buy at higher prices can now afford to
    buy more units.

31
Aggregate supply
  • Summing over the individual supply of each player
    we obtain the aggregate supply curve S(p), the
    total supply of the asset from those players who
    want to sell their shares, as a function of price
  • Following the same reasoning as on the previous
    slide, the supply curve is a step function which
    increases from minv1,v2, . . . ,vI, where the
    steps have variable length of si.

32
Indifferent traders
  • This only leaves stockholders whose valuation
    vi p, who are indifferent about how much they
    trade. They are equally well off selling up to
    their endowment si versus buying up to their
    budget constraint mi/p
  • The next step is to those prices for which
    there is excess supply, which we denote by p.
    Then we derive those prices for which there is
    excess demand, denoted p-.
  • The set of competitive equilibrium are the
    remaining prices.

33
Solving for competitive equilibrium
  • We find those prices for which there is excess
    supply, which we denote by p. Then we derive
    those prices for which there is excess demand,
    denoted p-. The set of competitive equilibrium
    are the remaining prices.
  • By definition the p prices are defined by the
    inequality that
  • Similarly the p- prices are defined by

34
Aggregate supply in the first example
  • At prices above 3, the third player will
    supply 4 units, and at price 3, the player is
    indifferent between supplying quantity between 0
    and 4. No one supplies anything to the market at
    less than 3.
  • Define q as any quantity satisfying the
    inequalities
  • Then the supply function is

35
Aggregate demand in the first example
  • To make the problem more manageable we will
    assume that traders can buy fractions of units,
    rather than just whole ones.
  • Then we can write the demand schedule as

36
Graph of supply and demand curves
37
Competitive Equilibrium in the first example
  • In this example, there is a unique equilibrium
    price at Note that at prices above , demand
    shrinks quite markedly because infra marginal
    demanders can no longer afford more than one
    unit. Similarly at prices below , demanders want
    considerably more than what producers can supply.
  • However at the unique equilibrium price not all
    demanders are able to fulfill their plans. In
    limit order markets those demanders who enter
    their orders first receive priority over those
    who recognize the equilibrium price later.

38
Aggregate supply in the second example
  • Recall that aggregate demand in the both
    examples is the same. We now derive supply as a
    function of price.
  • At prices above 3, the third player will
    supply 4 units, and at price 3, the player is
    indifferent between supplying quantity between 0
    and 4. No one supplies anything to the market at
    less than 3.
  • Define q as any quantity satisfying the
    inequalities
  • Then the supply function is

39
Supply and demand in second example
40
Competitive equilibrium in the second example
  • In this example, there is a band of equilibrium
    prices. At every price between and suppliers and
    demanders wish to trade units between them. At
    all these prices both demanders and suppliers are
    able to fulfill their plans.
  • However the price is not determined uniquely by
    the theory of competitive equilibrium. Whereas in
    the previous example demanders competed with each
    other for the limited supplier, here demanders
    and suppliers can bargain over who should receive
    the most gains from trading.

41
Optimality of competitive equilibrium
  • The prisoners dilemma illustrates why games
    reach outcomes in which all players are worse off
    than they would be in one of the other outcomes.
  • Notice that in a competitive equilibrium is a
    single the potential trading surplus is used up
    by the traders. It is impossible to make one or
    more players better off without making someone
    else worse off.
  • This important result explains why many
    economists recommend markets as a way of
    allocating resources.

42
But is competitive equilibrium realistic?
  • The short answer is maybe. Whether or not this is
    true depends on the
  • Cost structure
  • Durability and nature of product demand
  • Number of firms in the industry
  • Threat of entry by new firms
  • Clearly strategy consultants search for
    situations where these factors are not conducive
    to the existence of a competitive equilibrium.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com