Title: Lecture 5 Monopoly practice and the competitive limit
1Lecture 5Monopoly practice and the competitive
limit
The latter parts of the lecture analyze other
aspects of monopolistic practices. We discuss
mechanisms for setting prices and quantities, the
role of commitment, market segmentation, and
product bundling. Then we investigate the effects
of competition,the competitive limit and the
related concept of competitive equilibrium.
2A dynamic inconsistency?
But what if the monopolist set price so that
marginal revenue equals marginal cost, and the
demanders whose valuations exceeded the price
immediately purchased the item at the beginning
of the game?
3The static solution illustrated
Price in dollars
20
inverse demand curve
Uniform price solution
unit cost
10
marginal revenue curve
quantity
0
Uniform quantity solution
4Residual demand
Price
New vertical axis for origin of residual inverse
demand
20
Uniform price solution
Unit cost
10
New marginal revenue curve
Quantity
0
5Will price fall to marginal cost?
- The solution to this game is for the monopolist
to let the price decline to where marginal
revenue equals marginal cost at the end of the
game, thus presenting each consumer
simultaneously with a take it or leave it offer
at that price. - Equivalently, the monopolist can commit to a
uniform price policy by committing to everyone
the lowest price he offers to anyone. - Letting a firm split can also resolve the
problem if each of the new break off firms
guarantee to match each others discounts.
6Durable goods monopoly
- One way of avoiding the problem associated with
a random cut-off time is to rent the good for
short periods. - But this is not always possible, and it might
be desirable to attempt to price discriminate
between consumers. - There are two cases to focus on
- 1. Constant marginal cost
- 2. Fixed supply
7Discriminating monopolist
- Price and product discrimination is more
widespread than in durable goods problems, where
the monopolist may be able to sort customers by
their urgency. - Suppose the monopolist knows the valuations of
the players, and can commit to prices. - Make a take it or leave it offer to each
person multi person ultimatum game. - Now imagine that it cannot prevent players from
buying in any market they like. - Now let monopolist condition on characteristics
that are related to their valuations which he
cannot observe.
8Multiple markets
- Consider now another related method for
segmenting market demand to extract greater
economic rent. - The firm exploits the idea that customers who
demand several of the firms products might
exhibit more elastic demands (be more price
sensitive) than customers who only wish to
purchase a smaller subset of the firms products. - Perhaps the most common example of this
behavior is quantity discounting (sometimes
enforced through packaging).
9Other examples
- Firms sell assembled goods such as cars or other
durables for new car buyers and demand from
previous buyers, plus replacement parts arising
from collision damage or wear and tear. - Restaurants (furniture stores, car dealers) offer
complete dinners (suites, high performance and
luxury packages) with a limited (selected) range
of items, and also offer portions a la carte (set
pieces, individual components). - Ski resorts (amusement parks, cellular phone
companies internet or cable operators) offer
vacation packages for lodging and tickets (entry
or connection plus service charges) as well as
sell tickets (services) by themselves.
10A product bundling monopolist
- A resort owner has a monopoly over two
products, called accommodation on the mountain,
and ski lift tickets. - Some demanders visit the mountain resort to ski
downhill, while others come to cross country ski
or snowshoe (neither of which requires lift
tickets). Demanders also choose between commuting
from the city 90 minutes by road, or by renting
an apartments or a hotel room at the resort. - What should the resort owner charge for ski
tickets, for accommodation, and for the holiday
package of both?
11The number of rivals
- Now we investigate how the solution to trading
games is affected by relaxing the assumption that
there is only a single supplier (or more
generally dealer) in each market. - First we analyze how monopoly power breaks down
with competition from rival producers. - This leads us to define price taking behavior
and a definition of competitive equilibrium.
12The competitive limit
- We first consider two extensions of the
multiunit auction, where there is a constant
marginal cost of production. - In the first case we assume that entry occurs
sequentially until it is unprofitable to do so.
This corresponds to a competitive market where
rival suppliers compete for demanders. - In the second case we assume that the
monopolist or cartel maximizes producer surplus.
13Duopoly
Considering the monopoly problem of the previous
lecture, let us now introduce a second seller
with same marginal cost schedule, and no fixed
costs.
14Three or more producers
- Continuing in this vein, one could fragment the
organization of production even more. - For example consider how three or more
producers would compete against each other. - Can we endogenously determine the number of
entrants?
15Price competition and capacity constraints
- It seems that a remarkably small number of
competing firms suffice to drive the price down
to marginal cost. - But this result is partly driven by the cost
structure. - Now suppose there is a two stage game, where
firms construct capacity for production in the
first stage, and market their produce in a second
stage.
16Declining marginal cost
Now suppose unit costs fall with scale of
production. For example suppose there is a fixed
cost of entry (technological know how or plant
set up) as well as a constant marginal cost. If
there is only one producer, then the profit
maximizing quantity for the firm is What
happens in the case of two producers?
17Is there convergence?
- A natural question to ask is where this process
would converge, and whether there is an easy way
to model what would happen in the limit. - Do our experiments suggest that the limit point
depends on the cost structure? - Another question is how many firms are required
to reach this limit (that is when it exists).
18Free entry
- Consider first the uniform distribution. In a
second price auction - In the first case we assume that entry occurs
sequentially until it is unprofitable to do so.
This corresponds to a competitive market where
rival suppliers compete for demanders. - In the second case we assume that the
monopolist or cartel maximizes producer surplus.
19Definition of competitive equilibrium
A competitive equilibrium is a single price, or a
price band (an interval on the real line), with
two defining properties 1. Traders treat each
point in the competitive equilibrium as a fixed
price, seeking to buy or sell units of the good
that maximize their objective function at that
fixed price. 2. At every price above those in
the competitive equilibrium, demand exceeds
supply. At every price below those in the
competitive equilibrium, supply exceeds demand.
20Competitive equilibrium as a tool for prediction
- The key advantage from assuming that markets
are in competitive equilibrium is that models of
competitive equilibrium are relatively
straightforward to analyze. - For example, deriving the properties of a Nash
equilibrium solution to a trading game is
typically more complex than deriving the
competitive equilibrium for the same game. - In other words, using the tools of competitive
equilibrium we can sometimes make accurate
predictions with minimal effort.
21An economy with one stock
- Consider the following economy
- There is one stock, as well as money. The
common value of the asset is constant, and every
one is fully informed. - There are a finite number of player types, say
I. Every player belonging to a given player type
has the same asset and money endowment, and the
same private valuation. - Players belonging to type i are distinguished
by their initial endowment of money mi and the
stock si, as well as their private valuation of
the stock vi. Thus a player type i is defined by
the triplet (mi, si, vi).
22Example 1
- To make matters more concrete, suppose there
are 10 players, with private valuations that take
on the integer values from 1 to 10. - Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
endowed with 4 units of the good, and everybody
else has 12 to buy units of the good. - We also assume that everyone has the same
access to the market, and can place limit or
market orders.
23The front page of a players folio.
24Example 2
- Now we modify the example a little.
- To make matters more concrete, suppose there are
10 players, with private valuations that take on
the integer values from 1 to 10. - Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
endowed with 4 units of the good, and everybody
else has 12 to buy units of the good. - As before we assume that everyone has the same
access to the market, and can place limit or
market orders.
25The front page
26Using supply and demand curves to derive
competitive equilibrium
- To derive the competitive equilibrium, compute
the demand for the asset minus the supply of the
asset (both as a function of price), otherwise
known as the net demand for the asset. - Then aggregate across players to obtain the
aggregate net demand. - The set of competitive equilibrium prices is
found by applying the second part of the
definition every price below (above) prices in
the set generate positive (negative) aggregate
net demand.
27Individual optimization in a competitive
equilibrium
- In a competitive equilibrium with price p the
objective of player i is to pick the quantity of
stock traded, denoted qi, to maximize the value
of his or her portfolio subject to constraints
that prevent short sales (selling more stock than
the the seller holds) or bankruptcy (not having
enough liquidity to cover purchases). - The value of the portfolio of player i is
28Constraints in the optimization problem
The short sale constraint is
The solvency constraint is
These constraints can be combined as
29Solution to the individualsoptimization problem
The solution to this linear problem is to
specialize the stock if vi exceeds p, specialize
in money if p exceeds vi, and choose any feasible
quantity q if vi p. That is
and
30Aggregate demand
- Summing across the individual demands of players
we obtain the demand across players curve D(p). - Let 1 . . . be an indicator function, taking a
value of 1 if the statement inside the
parentheses is true, and 0 if false. Then, the
demand from those players who wish to increase
their holding of the stock is
- Thus D(p) declines in steps, for two reasons.
As p falls the number of players with valuations
exceeding p increases, and demanders who are
willing to buy at higher prices can now afford to
buy more units.
31Aggregate supply
- Summing over the individual supply of each player
we obtain the aggregate supply curve S(p), the
total supply of the asset from those players who
want to sell their shares, as a function of price
- Following the same reasoning as on the previous
slide, the supply curve is a step function which
increases from minv1,v2, . . . ,vI, where the
steps have variable length of si.
32Indifferent traders
- This only leaves stockholders whose valuation
vi p, who are indifferent about how much they
trade. They are equally well off selling up to
their endowment si versus buying up to their
budget constraint mi/p
- The next step is to those prices for which
there is excess supply, which we denote by p.
Then we derive those prices for which there is
excess demand, denoted p-. - The set of competitive equilibrium are the
remaining prices.
33Solving for competitive equilibrium
- We find those prices for which there is excess
supply, which we denote by p. Then we derive
those prices for which there is excess demand,
denoted p-. The set of competitive equilibrium
are the remaining prices. - By definition the p prices are defined by the
inequality that
- Similarly the p- prices are defined by
34Aggregate supply in the first example
- At prices above 3, the third player will
supply 4 units, and at price 3, the player is
indifferent between supplying quantity between 0
and 4. No one supplies anything to the market at
less than 3. - Define q as any quantity satisfying the
inequalities
- Then the supply function is
35Aggregate demand in the first example
- To make the problem more manageable we will
assume that traders can buy fractions of units,
rather than just whole ones. - Then we can write the demand schedule as
36Graph of supply and demand curves
37Competitive Equilibrium in the first example
- In this example, there is a unique equilibrium
price at Note that at prices above , demand
shrinks quite markedly because infra marginal
demanders can no longer afford more than one
unit. Similarly at prices below , demanders want
considerably more than what producers can supply. - However at the unique equilibrium price not all
demanders are able to fulfill their plans. In
limit order markets those demanders who enter
their orders first receive priority over those
who recognize the equilibrium price later.
38Aggregate supply in the second example
- Recall that aggregate demand in the both
examples is the same. We now derive supply as a
function of price. - At prices above 3, the third player will
supply 4 units, and at price 3, the player is
indifferent between supplying quantity between 0
and 4. No one supplies anything to the market at
less than 3. - Define q as any quantity satisfying the
inequalities
- Then the supply function is
39Supply and demand in second example
40Competitive equilibrium in the second example
- In this example, there is a band of equilibrium
prices. At every price between and suppliers and
demanders wish to trade units between them. At
all these prices both demanders and suppliers are
able to fulfill their plans. - However the price is not determined uniquely by
the theory of competitive equilibrium. Whereas in
the previous example demanders competed with each
other for the limited supplier, here demanders
and suppliers can bargain over who should receive
the most gains from trading.
41Optimality of competitive equilibrium
- The prisoners dilemma illustrates why games
reach outcomes in which all players are worse off
than they would be in one of the other outcomes. - Notice that in a competitive equilibrium is a
single the potential trading surplus is used up
by the traders. It is impossible to make one or
more players better off without making someone
else worse off. - This important result explains why many
economists recommend markets as a way of
allocating resources.
42But is competitive equilibrium realistic?
- The short answer is maybe. Whether or not this is
true depends on the - Cost structure
- Durability and nature of product demand
- Number of firms in the industry
- Threat of entry by new firms
- Clearly strategy consultants search for
situations where these factors are not conducive
to the existence of a competitive equilibrium.