Title: Familias en Accion
1Familias en Accion The Introduction and Abolition
of a Conditional Cash Transfer David
Phillips EDePo and IFS
2Outline
- the Familias en acción Program A focus on
education. - Evaluation methodology Introduction of the
programme. - 3. Results of the Policy
- 4. What if the programme were abolished?
- 5. Results and methological implications
- Lessons to be learned.
3Familias en acción (FeA)
- Familias en Accion is a Conditional Cash Transfer
program. Its primary aim is to foster the
accumulation of human capital. -
- It gives monetary incentives for families to
invest in childrens human capital (education and
health) - Similar conditional cash transfers are being
implemented in - Mexico, Honduras, Nicaragua, Panama, Brazil,
Argentina, Turkey, Bangladesh - In Colombia, the program is targeted towards the
poorest 20 of households. It was initially
limited to those living in semi-rural
municipalities with fewer than 100k people, with
enough education and health infrastructure, and
with a bank, but is now being extended to major
urban areas too.
4Familias en acción (FeA)
- The program has two main components Health and
Education - Nutrition and health
- Eligible families with children aged 0-5 receive
about 30US per month conditional on registering
the children on growth development checkups - Mothers are also encouraged to attend some
talks with health professionals - Education
- Eligible families with children aged 6-17
receive a subsidy per child conditional on school
attendance. - All subsidies are given to the mothers. Why?
5Educational Subsidies
- The educational component of FeA consists of a
subsidy of about 10 per month per child enrolled
in primary school and 20 per month per child in
secondary school, provided their attendance is at
least 80. -
- What is the economic case for this intervention?
6Educational Subsidies
If credit constraints were the full story then
unconditional subsidies would suffice.
Conditionality implies externalities are seen as
a key issue. Redistribution Traditional
redistribution has efficiency costs in terms of
reduced human capital investment and work
incentives. This programme redistributes to the
poor in a way that counteracts this general
effect.
7Targeting the Programme
- How do we define the poorest 20 for the
programme when income is often volatile and
income data absent? - SISBEN is a socio-economic classification system
designed by the Colombian government which takes
account of physical living standards (e.g whether
they have electricity, quality of walls/roof
etc). Eligibility is currently defined on 1999
status. - So what are the eligible families like?
- Average family size 7
- Average monthly consumption 150 per month (inc
consumption in-kind) - Food consumption is about 60 of total
consumption.
8Evaluating the Programme
How do you evaluate the impact of this programme
on school enrolment? We use a treatment-control
methodology where the programme is implemented in
some areas but not others.
So whats the problem? We dont observe
because those in treatment areas are only
observed in period t1 having been treated.
9Evaluation Methodology
The ideal way to solve this problem is to
randomly allocate treatment across individuals
or, in this case, municipalities. With random
sampling we have
But, politics intervened. The Colombian
government wanted to roll out the policy wherever
the necessary infrastructure was in place, so the
controls we had were a selected
sample Typically, without banks and somewhat
poorer health/education infrastructure. So what
did we do?
10Evaluation Methodology
We still use the control municipalities as our
counterfactual, but account for the potential
pre-existing differences in school enrolment
prior to programme implementation. We combine two
standard evaluation techniques to accomplish
this 1) Selection on Observables 2)
Difference-in-Differences (Programme effect is
the difference between treatment and control
areas minus pre-existing differences)
Underlying the evaluation is comprehensive high
quality dataset with individual, household and
area information.
11Selection on Observables
Y a bX cD u where X are observables, D a
dummy indicating treatment and u
unobserved. If EDuX 0 (i.e. orthogonal), we
can get an unbiased estimator of the effect of
treatment by the coefficient c. We can
generalise this approach with Propensity Score
Matching. This method defines P(D1X) P(X)
the probability of being treated given your
observable characteristics, termed the
propensity score. We then estimate the impact
of the programme by comparing people with similar
propensity scores but different treatment
statuses.
12Difference-in-Differences
Up until now we have assumed that, conditional
upon observables X, treatment and control areas
are identical. But, what if we have the model Y
a bX cD u v with EXv / 0 In
this case, we get biased estimates of the impact
of D they are confounded by the impact of v. How
do we get around this? If v is constant over
time (a fixed effect) and we have pre and
post-programme data we can use difference-in-diffe
rences method.
13Difference in difference effect
Y
treatment
effect
Control
t1
t0
We also call the fixed effect a Common Time
Trend Assumption
14Example diff-in-diff effect
- Before the program, school enrolment rates
- In treatment towns 60
- In control towns 50
- After the program,
- in treatment towns 80
- in control towns 60
- What is the effect of the program ?
15Answer
16The Data
- Sample 11,500 households in 67 treatment and 62
control municipalities - Baseline collected between June and November 2002
- First follow up collected between July and
December 2003 - Second follow up collected between November 2005
and April 2006. - Complete household survey. Info about all
household members. Household survey is quite
long about three hours and a half - Questionnaires to household heads, mothers
etc.... - Survey to major, health care centres, schools,
nurseries - Good quality of data attrition 6 between the
baseline and first follow-up. About a further 9
between first and second follow-up.
17Table 1. Impact of FA on percentage of children
who attend school
Statistically significantly different from zero
at the 5 significance level.
18Impact on School Enrolment
- Higher impacts in rural areas.
- Strong significant impacts upon older children.
- No significant impact upon younger children.
- Remaining issues
- Has it affected quality of education?
- How does the effect operate?
- - our approach doesnt allow us to investigate
credit/price channels and might reflect things
other than response to the monetary incentive
only.
19Other Impacts of the Programme
- Increased Consumption
- This is increase is mainly in high quality
foodstuffs (meat and dairy) childrens clothes
and shoes and educational goods and services. - No increase in alcohol, tobacco and adults
clothes. - Health
- Increase in attendance of health classes
- Lower risk of disease in rural areas
(diarrhoea!) - Increased height-for-age.
20Summary (part 1)
- Familias en Accion is an education subsidy in
Colombia - It was evaluated using a difference-in-difference
methodology comparing treatment and control
areas. - It had a significant positive impact on school
enrolment for older children
Looking Ahead
- What might happen if the programme were
abolished? - How would we go about evaluating this without
actually testing abolition in some areas? - What conclusions do we draw from this work?
21Todays political context
The Colombian government is presently expanding
the programme to cover urban areas. Doing this
will be expensive and it plans to help fund this
by abolishing the payments to children aged 11 or
under. Why? Because the results of the
evaluation showed the programme had little impact
on this group. Is this a sensible argument? Not
really, because the programme may have had
dynamic effects.
22Dynamic effects of Familias
- The outcome (school enrolment) can still be
affected by past-exposure to the programme. For
instance - the subsidy has meant older children are more
likely to remain in school. In order to protect
their investment in these children, who may have
demonstrated otherwise hidden abilities, parents
may withdraw younger children (who can go back to
school later). - the subsidy may have changed preferences.
Families may have got used to extra consumption
(and withdraw more children to continue to fund
this) or, alternatively may have a greater
preference for education.
23Measurement Issues
- How could we test the impact of abolishing FeA?
- We could withdraw the programme from a
(preferably) random selection of areas and use
the same methods as before - But this would be politically difficult.
Instead, we could elicit information directly
from survey respondents by asking what they
do. This is called the stated response method and
is treated with scepticism by many economists.
24The stated-response questions
We ask respondents the following
question Suppose the government withdraws the
subsidy. Would you withdraw your child(ren) from
school? Yes or no. If respondents answer Yes
they are then required to state whether all or
some, with those stating some then asked to
indicate which children. We use the same
methodology to ask what would happen if the
subsidy were made unconditional cash transfer to
families with children.
25Why sceptical?
We want to use our stated response as
follows Y a bX u Y stated withdrawal
decision X household, village or child
characteristic With this in mind, what kind of
problems are the most serious?
26Measurement Error
Y a bX u
- What happens when Y is measured with different
kinds of error? - (1) If Eu 0 and EXu 0 (i.e. white
noise), our estimates of a and b are unbiased but
have greater variance. - (2) If Y is consistently stated too high or too
low, our constant term a is biased. - (3) If EXu / 0 (i.e. correlation between the
reporting errors, u and explanatory variables,
X) then our estimates of b are biased. - Hence we should be mainly concerned if we believe
we have correlated errors.
27Withdrawal Decisions
Appear reasonable withdrawal rates not large
enough to indicate significant strategic response
and higher for older/rural.
28Withdrawals by Age
29Withdrawals by Age
30Checking Reliability
- In applied evaluation work its important to
investigate the plausibility and reliability of
your results - Is withdrawal correlated in the expected way
with family characteristics? - Are results robust to changing specifications or
samples?
31Withdrawal Decisions
Regression shows that withdrawal is related in
the expected manner with household
characteristics Younger children Living closer
to school in urban areas With educated
mothers And high household incomes Are less
likely to be withdrawn from their school! But, a
larger number of households than expected (almost
60) say that they would withdraw all of their
children, although this might reflect large fixed
costs in sending your family to school.
32Why so many young withdrawn?
- Look back a few slides. Notice that although
withdrawal isnt so high as to be implausible,
MANY more young children are being reported to be
withdrawn than were induced to start school by
the programme. Why? - One possibility is intra-household effects.
- By inducing older children to remain in school,
maybe they have greater attachment and have shown
otherwise hidden abilities. - Houses that are credit-constrained may
reallocate resources to the older ones because
the young ones can, arguably catch up. - We do find that young children with older
siblings are more likely to be withdrawn!
33Why so many young withdrawn?
- But this doesnt seem to be an intra-household
story. - Over 8/10 of the younger children withdrawn come
from households where all of the children are
being withdrawn and hence no substitution
could possibly take place. - What could be driving our results?
- The structure of the question parents answering
all due to inability to decide on the spot, an
unwillingness to reveal preferences over children
to the interviewer (and in front of children), or
just a choice of the easy option.
34Why so many young withdrawn?
Statistically speaking, we have problem (3)
discussed above. The presence of older children
(who parents wish to withdraw from school) is
positively correlated with measurement error in
withdrawal, and it is this correlation we
observe, not any underlying intra-household
effect. Lesson The structure of a question is
very important in its reliability. Whilst our
question seems very reliably to ascertain which
HOUSEHOLDS withdraw children, less good at
finding which children WITHIN the households
because we make the mistake of letting parents
say ALL
35An Unconditional Subsidy?
Few respondents say they would withdraw if it
were made unconditional this indicates that
credit-constraints play a key role in low school
attendance, with externalities less important.
36An Unconditional Subsidy?
- But this does not make a convincing case for
unconditionality - it would significantly increase the cost of the
programme. - the impact in rural areas is not insignificant.
- it might undermine support for the policy.
37Conclusions (1)
- Economists use both selection on observables
and difference-in-differences methods when
completely randomised trials are unavailable. - Familias en Accion had a significantly positive
effect on school enrolment in Colombia. - This was most notable in rural areas, and for
older children - But our methodology does not allow investigation
of the channels credit constraints
externalities/prices or attitudes
38Conclusions (2)
- The impact of withdrawing a programme is not
necessarily equal and opposite of introducing
it. - Stated-response methods are a potential way of
evaluating withdrawing a successful and
politically sensitive problem. - However, question regimes need to be designed
very carefully to ensure reliable response. They
are best seen as a complement to traditional
experimental approaches. - Responses to our questions
- - possibility of dynamic programme effects
- - the importance of credit-constraints as
channel. - Whilst not directly comparable, Colombia should
be cautious about removing subsidies for young
children.
39References
Fitzsimons, Phillips and Vera-Hernandez (2007)
What would you do? An investigation of
stated-response data IFS/EDePo working paper
http//www.ifs.org.uk/edepo/wps/ewp0701.pdf Thoma
s, Beegle et al (2004) Education in a crisis,
Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 74, pages
53 - 85